Competitive Markets When Customers ∗ Anticipate Stockouts CaryDeckA,B AmyFarmerA JoshuaFosterC A UniversityofArkansas B ChapmanUniversity C UniversityofWisconsin-Oshkosh August7,2016 Abstract Retailersoftenworryabouthowshopperswillreactwhentheyfindanemptyshelf,but theanticipationofexperiencingastockoutmayalsoimpactcustomerbehavior. Thisinturn affects a retailer’s optimal price and inventory choices. In this paper we explore how the feasibilityofvisitingasecondsellerinadifferentiatedproductduopolyimpactsmarketout- comesusingacombinationoftheoreticalmodeling, experiments, andsimulations. Behav- iorally,whenshopperscanonlyvisitasinglesellertheyoverweightheprobabilityofbeing stockedoutandavoidasellertheyexpecttobetoocrowded. Aresultofthisisthataseller maysellmoreunitsbystockingalowerinventory. Subjectsellersappeartoanticipatethis reaction when making price and inventory choices. However, when it is costless to visit a secondseller,customersfollowtheirdominantstrategies. Whilesubjectsellersareobserved toengageinexcessivepricecompetition,theydonotunderstock. Keywords: OnShelfAvailability,MarketEntryGame,ShopperReaction,Experiments JELClassification: D40,G31,L15,C91 ∗DeckgratefullyacknowledgesfinancialsupportfromtheCenterforRetailExcellenceforthisproject.Theauthors wishtothanktheseminarparticipantsatWashingtonStateUniversity,theattendeesofthe2014SouthernEconomic AssociationAnnualMeetings,andBrendanJoyceforexcellentresearchassistance. 1 COMPETITIVEMARKETSWHENCUSTOMERSANTICIPATESTOCKOUTS 2 “Noonegoesthereanymore. It’stoocrowded.” -YogiBerra Stockoutsarepotentiallycostlytoretailerswhentheyrepresentmissedsalesopportunities. Ashoppersearchingforaspecificitemmaydecidetopurchasenothing,purchaseasubstitute good, or shop elsewhere if faced with an empty shelf.1 Gruen et al. (2002) find that about half of stockouts result in the purchase of a substitute product. In this case the profitability ofthesellermaybepositivelyornegativelyaffecteddependingontherelativeprofitabilityof thesubstituteitem(seeKamakuraandRussell1989foranempiricalstudysuggestingpeople tendtotradeup). MahajanandvanRyzin(1999)provideageneralsurveyoftheliteratureon the impact of substitution on inventory management. Alternatively, the shopper may simply decidetoabandontheirshoppingcartandvisitacompetitorinstead.Thisdecisiondependson thepriceandselectionofferedbyarivalstore.2 Matsa(2011)findsthatgrocerystoreswithmore competition,especiallyfromWalmart,aremorelikelytoavoidshortfalls.3 Ofcourse,retailers mayprefertorunoutofstockiftheycanofferrainchecks(seeHessandGerstner1987)oras part of a bait and switch (see Wilke, et al. 1998a,b and Hess and Gerstner 1998). Even when shoppersarewillingtowait,thesellermayincurbackordercompensationcoststhatnegative impactprofits(Chenetal. 2015). Theimpactofstockoutscanextendbeyondasingleshopping trip. Andersonetal. (2006)showthatcurrentstockoutsimpactfuturepurchases(seealsoJing andLewis2011). Recently, there have been several papers dealing with the optimal pricing of a good con- ditional on inventory levels (see Chen and Simichi-Levi 2010 for a survey).4 One inventory situationthathasbeenstudiedextensivelyismarkdownpricing,wherethesellerhasmultiple periodsoverwhichitsellsproductsandcanmarkremaininginventorydowntoinducesales. Forexample,CachonandSwinney(2009)considertheinventoryproblemfacedbyasellerwho anticipatesdroppingitspriceatsomepointduringtheseason. LiuandvanRyzin(2008)con- siderstockoutriskasawaytoinducecustomerstobuyearlierintheseason(seealsoAvivand Pazgal 2008, Allon and Bassamboo 2011, and Liu and van Ryzin 2011). Many of these opti- 1ConcernabouthowshoppersreacttoastockoutgoesbacktoatleastWalterandGrabner(1975). Morerecently, Honhon, etal. (2010)offersadynamicprogrammingsolutiontotheoptimalassortmentproblemwhencustomers engageinstockout-basedsubstitution. 2BalachanderandFarquhar(1995)suggestthatinsomecircumstancesstockoutsmayhaveapositiveeffectonprice competition. 3SeeChaouch(2001),NagarajanandRajagopalan(2008)forsimilarmethodsofminimizinginventoryshortages. 4Whilemuchoftheliteratureoninventorypricingisseparatefromtheliteratureonsubstitutabilitybetweenprod- ucts,arecentpaperbyTranschel(2011)looksattheinterplaybetweenthetwo. 3 DECK,C.,A.FARMERANDJ.FOSTER malpricingpapersfocusonsellerswhoareinsulatedfromcompetitionordonottakeshopper expectationsintoaccount.5 If shopping is costly (in terms of time, gas, etc.), then customers may be captive to the retaileronthatshoppingtrip.However,priortovisitingtheseller,customerswillchoosewhere to shop based upon their perceived likelihood of finding the desired product in stock, which is a function of the quantity the retailer carries and the expected behavior of other shoppers, in addition to standard considerations such as price (travel costs, loyalty, etc.). This creates a variation of a “market entry game” played by shoppers who want to coordinate their actions aseachshopperpreferstonotexperienceanemptyshelf, butwantstopursuethebetterdeal ifshewillbesuccessful. Inthetraditionalmarketentrygame,playersprivatelydecideifthey wish to take a sure payoff or enter a pool where payoffs are decreasing in the total number of entrants. This game is modeled on firms deciding to enter a market where a monopolist would earn more than a duopolist who in turn would earn more than a triopolist and so on. The tension arises because there is a threshold number of entrants below which one wants to enterandabovewhichonedoesnot. Hence,inequilibriumonlysomefirmsshouldenterthe market,butabsentasymmetriesthereisacoordinationproblemastowhotheentrantsshould be. Controlled laboratory experiments have consistently found that people quickly converge toequilibriumbehaviorinaggregatedespiteconsiderableindividualheterogeneity(Rapoport 1995,Sundali,etal. 1995,Rapoport,etal. 1998,Ochs(1999)andRapoportandSeale(2008). In fact,thispatternissostrikingthatKahneman(1988)describesitasbeing“magic.”However,as thecoordinationproblembecomesmoredifficultdueforexampletooverconfidence(Camerer andLovallo1999)orambiguity(BrandtsandYao2010)excessentryisoftenobserved. When sellers create a market entry game for shoppers, carrying a larger inventory may induce more shoppers to visit a store if the shoppers believe that they are more likely to find the item. Alternatively, a seller could end up with excess inventory on the shelf if customers falselyanticipateastockoutbecausetheyoverestimatetheprobabilitythatothershopperswill visittheseller. EveryoneavoidingastoretheybelievewillstockoutistheretailvariantofYogi Berra’sfamousquipaboutnoonegoingthereanymorebecauseitistoocrowded. Theresultis thathavingexcessinventorycouldbeasignthattoolittleortoomuchinventorywasordered. Inthissetting,pricebecomesadoubleedgedswordfortheretailer. Loweringthepricemakes the seller more attractive, which should increase the number of shoppers who visit; but, this 5NagarajanandRajagopalan(2009)lookatamodelwherefirmsconsiderstockout-basedsubstitutionandcompeti- torinventoryinanewsvendorstyleduopoly,whileAnderhubetal.(2003)providesexperimentalevidenceforpricing strategiesinduopolieswithheterogeneousgoodsandcapacityconstraints. COMPETITIVEMARKETSWHENCUSTOMERSANTICIPATESTOCKOUTS 4 makesavisitriskierandmayhavetheunwantedeffectofactuallydiscouragingshoppers. This paper examines how the potential for stockouts affects buyers’ decisions regarding where to shop. We first construct a theoretical model with a three stage game in which two sellers offer differentiated products with one being superior to the other (i.e. customers have agreaterwillingnesstopayforthehighqualityseller’sproduct). Thehighqualitysellerpre- commitstoaninventorylevel,thenbothsellerspostprices,andfinallyshoppersselectwhich seller to visit and attempt to make purchases. If it is costless to visit the low quality seller afterexperiencingastockoutatthehighqualityseller,thenallshoppersinitiallyvisittheseller offeringthebestdeal. However,ifitisprohibitivelycostlyforshopperstovisitasecondstore, thenthenumberofshopperswhovisiteachsellerdependsontheinventorylevelofthehigh qualitysellerandthebuyersurplus(valueminusprice)ateachlocation.Themodelwedevelop isintheveinofDeneckereandPeck(1995);however,intheirmodel,sellersofferahomogenous product and shoppers are limited to visiting a single seller (see also Peters 1984). Despite the relativesimplicityofthemodel,itisnotpossibletofindananalyticalsolutionforasymmetric equilibrium.6 Therefore, we rely upon simulations and controlled laboratory experiments to understand this situation. Behaviorally, we find that shoppers are reluctant to visit the high quality seller as its inventory increases when stockouts are costly, a result that is consistent withprobabilityweightingandyieldsbehaviorinlinewithYogiBerra’sstatement. 1 Theoretical Model Supposetherearetwosellersofferingverticallydifferentiatedproducts,oneofhighquality andoneoflowquality,tonshoppers. DefinethetwosellersasH andL,respectively. Assume each of the n shoppers desires only one unit. Further, assume all shoppers are identical and value the respective products at V and V , where V > V . Shoppers each independently H L H L make a decision regarding the product to purchase, and visit that seller initially. However, thereisapossibilityofastockoutatthehighqualityseller. Ifthisoccurs, ashoppercanthen choose to visit the low quality seller at some cost, which is captured by depreciating V by a L factorofδ. Forsimplicityweconsiderthecaseswhereδ =0,1capturingaprohibitivecostand nocostrespectively. Further,itisassumedthelowqualitysellerwillhavesufficientquantityto servethemarket. 6Therearealsoasymmetricequilibriasuchasexactlymshoppersoutofnfollowapurestrategytovisitaparticular seller. Thereareotherequilibriawheresomeshoppersfollowpurestrategiesofvisitingthehighqualitysellerornot whileothershoppersdosoprobabilistically. 5 DECK,C.,A.FARMERANDJ.FOSTER Given this structure, the type H seller will choose the inventory capacity C ∈ [0,C] they wouldliketocarry,whereitisassumedC < n. Highqualityinventoryhasaperunitholding costK < V ,whichissunkoncetheproductisprocured. Thiscostcanbethoughtofeither C H as a direct cost associated with the high quality product such as an actual price paid to the supplierorthecostofadjustingdisplayspaceoranopportunitycostassociatedwithforegone salesofsomealternativeproductthatcouldhavebeencarried. Forsimplicity,bothsellersare assumedtohavenomarginalcost.Oncethehighqualityseller’sinventorylevelisdetermined, itbecomescommonknowledge,bothsellersprivatelyandsimultaneouslysetprices,andthen shoppersmaketheirpurchasingdecisions.7 Giventhisgeneralsetup,thestagesofthegameareasfollows: Stage0: Naturechoosesthedepreciationfactor,δ,andthenumberofshoppers,n. Stage1: ThetypeH sellerchoosesitsinventorylevel,C conditionalonδandn. Stage2: EachsellerchoosesP fori=H,LconditionalonC,δ,andn. i Stage3: ShoppersmakepurchasedecisionsconditionalonP ,P ,C,δ,andn. H L Throughout this paper the business setting is taken to be a retail market where the high qualitysellercanbethoughtofasasmallspecialtyshopwithlimitedspaceandthelowquality sellercanbethoughtofasageneralmerchandiserthatcarriesmanysimilarsubstituteproducts. Inthissense,thecapacitychoicecanbetakenasthecurrentinventoryofthespecialtyretailer or as its store size, which was a choice variable when the specialty shop opened. However, the model applies equally well to other business settings. For example, boutique restaurants oftenhavelimitedseatingorsuppliesoffreshqualityingredientswhilefastfoodchainshavea seeminglylimitlesssupply. Before analyzing the game we note that although our setup is similar to the newsvendor problem(e.g. SchweitzerandCachon2000andNagarajanandRajagopalan2009)itisdistinct inthatdemandisendogenouslydeterminedbythestrategicinterplayoffirmsengagedinprice settingcompetition.8 OurmodelisalsosimilartothequantityprecommitmentmodelofKreps andScheinkman(1983). However,inourcasecustomersonlyfacethepossibilityofastockout at one of the sellers. The reason for this design choice is that we are particularly interested in how the possibility of experiencing a stockout impacts shopper behavior. If stockouts are possibleatbothsellers,thentheout-of-stockriskmaybeneutralized. Onlyallowingthehigh 7ForadiscussionofasimilarproblemwhereavailabilityisunobservedseeDana(2001). 8Althoughpricehasbeenintroducedintothenewsvendorproblem,itistypicallytreatedasashiftinastochastic demand(seePetruzziandDada1999). COMPETITIVEMARKETSWHENCUSTOMERSANTICIPATESTOCKOUTS 6 qualitysellertostockoutcreatesthedesiredshoppertensionbetweenasafeoptionandarisky dealwithahigherpotentialpayoff. Solving for the equilibrium requires backward induction; thus we begin with the shopper behaviorinstage3. Giventhatweconsiderhomogeneousshopperswhoarenotabletocoordi- natetheiractions,wefocusonsymmetricequilibria. Itisassumedthenrisk-neutralshoppers willchoosetheproductthatoffersthegreaterexpectedsurplus. Assuch,thedecisionwhether to seek the high quality product depends upon their valuation of both products less the re- spective prices as well as the probability one can obtain the product from the type H seller if visited. Each consumer’s strategy space is as follows: {H,L}, {H,∅}, {L,∅} and {∅,∅} where thefirstelementistheretailertheyvisitinitially,andthesecondentryindicateswhetherthey wouldvisitLconditionedonhavingexperiencedastockoutatH initially. Thisstrategyspace alsoreflectstheabilityforashoppertovisitneithersellershouldbothofferanegativesurplus. Since pricing above value results in zero revenue to the seller, a type i seller will set P ≤ V . i i IntheeventofastockoutatH,itisassumedthattheC unitsarerandomlyallocatedtothem shopperswhovisitedH.9 Letλdenotetheprobabilitythatanindividualshoppervisitsthehighqualitysellerinitially. The surplus that a shopper obtains from a type i seller is given by V −P . If the low quality i i selleroffersasurplusgreaterorequaltoH,thenallshopperswillvisitL.10 Thatis,ifV −P ≥ L L V −P thenλ*=0. H H If,ontheotherhand,V −P <V −P thenshoppersfaceatensionbetweenthecertain L L H H yetlowersurplusfromLandtryingforthehighsurplusfromH.Theirdecisiondependsonthe chanceofnotbeingstockedoutatHandthedepreciatingfactor,δ.Letp(λ|C,Q)representthe probabilityashoppersuccessfullymakesapurchaseatthehighqualityseller,iftheQ=n−1 otherconsumersgowithprobabilityλtosellerH whohasC units. Theexpectedsurplusfrom thedecisiontovisitH isgivenbythefollowing. p(λ|C,Q)(V −P )+[1−p(λ|C,Q)]max{δV −P ,0} (1) H H L L WhenV −P <V −P thevalueδtakesin(1)willeithermakevisitingH firstariskyor L L H H risklessdecisionfortheshopper. Thustherearetwocasestoconsider. 9Thiswouldbethecaseifarrivalorderwasrandomandcustomerswereservedonafirst-comefirst-servedbasis. 10Thetheoreticalresultspresentedbelowarenotsensitivetothistie-breakingassumption. 7 DECK,C.,A.FARMERANDJ.FOSTER 1.1 Case1: ConsumersFaceACostlessStockout(δ = 1) 1.1.1 Stage3: ShoppersMakePurchasingDecisions In this case a shopper who plays {H,L} and experiences a stockout will receive the same surplus as a shopper who plays {L,∅}. The condition to visit H becomes p(λ | C,Q)(V − H P )+[1−p(λ|C,Q)](V −P )>V −P ,whichholdssolongasV −P <V −P . Thus H L L L L L L H H inthiscasethereisadominantstrategytovisitthehighqualitysellerfirst,λ*=1. 1.1.2 Stage2: SellersSetPrices In stage 2, H and L simultaneously choose their respective prices, P and P , given the H L high quality seller’s capacity, C, and anticipating the reaction of shoppers in stage 3. When δ = 1, L’sprofitfunctionisdiscontinuous. IfV −P ≥ V −P , thennshopperswillvisit H H L L H first. Thisleadstoastockout,andthen−C shopperswhowereunabletoprocureaunitat H willvisitL. However,ifLsetsapricethatyieldsV −P <V −P ,thenLcapturesalln H H L L shoppers. Equation(2)definesL’sprofitfunction. (n−C)PL ifVH −PH ≥VL−PL Π = (2) L nPL otherwise Thefirstcomponentinequation(2)showsLcansetarelativelyhighprice,butensuresitwill receiverelativelyfewshopperswhenitdoesso. Thesecondcomponentinequation(2)shows Lcanservetheentiremarket,butmustsetarelativelylowpricetodoso. H’s profit is also discontinuous. Should H offer a non-negative surplus and V −P ≥ H H V −P then H will sell all C units in its inventory. However, should it be that V −P < L L H H max{V −P ,0}thenH sellsnothing. ThisleadstothefollowingprofitfunctionforH. L L C(PH −KC) ifVH −PH ≥VL−PL,0 Π = (3) H −CKC otherwise From(3)itisclearthatH wantstoofferthegreatersurplusandthuspreventLfromcapturing the entire market. Additionally, L will also want to offer the greater surplus when the profit from doing so is greater than offering the smaller surplus and capturing the residual market, n − C. Given P , the profit to L for offering the greater surplus is greater than that from H COMPETITIVEMARKETSWHENCUSTOMERSANTICIPATESTOCKOUTS 8 capturingtheresidualmarketwhenn(V −(V −P )) > (n−C)V whereV −(V −P ) L H H L L H H isthepricethatequatesthesurplusfromeachfirm. RearrangingintermsofP wefindthatL H willpreferofferingagreatersurplusthanH whenP > V − CV ,whichisstrictlypositive H H n L giventheassumptionsthatV >V andC <n. H L Itisrelativelystraight-forwardtodemonstratetherewillbeamixedstrategyinpricingfor eitherfirmgiventheseassumptions. Forinstance,ifH setsapriceofP =V −CV ,thenL’s H H n L bestresponseisP∗ = V ,anofferofzerosurplustotheshopper. However,H’sbestresponse L L to L’s zero surplus is to offer a surplus marginally greater than zero, thus raising its price to P∗ = V − (cid:15). Yet now that P − (cid:15) > V − CV , L has an incentive to offer the greater H H H H n L surplustocustomers. This‘one-upping’insurplusofferingsbetweenfirmsdemonstratesthat theequilibriumpricingstrategywillbemixed. To define the mixed strategy over prices, let the surplus, s , offered by firm i, be drawn i from the distribution F where F (s ) = 0 and F (s ) = 1. It is assumed that F (·) is differen- i i i i i i tiableeverywhere. Theprobabilitydensityfunctionwillbedenotedbyf ,whichdescribesthe i probabilitywithwhichafirmwillchooseagivensurplus. GiventhemixedstrategyofH andthatP = V −s ,theexpectedprofittoLofofferinga i i i surplusofsis F (s)(V −s)n+(1−F (s))[n−C](V −s). (4) H L H L TogenerateindifferenceinL,weset(4)equaltothegreatestprofitLcanunilaterallyguarantee itselfwithapurestrategy. The‘securityprofit’thatLcanunilaterallyguaranteeitselfisgiven bysettingapriceP∗ =V andthereforesellingn−C units. Thus,Πs =(n−C)V . Setting(4) L L L L equaltoΠs andsolvingforF (s)yieldsthemixedstrategy L H n−C s F (s)= (5) H C V −s L wheres∈(cid:2)0,CV (cid:3). TheexpectedsurplusforH,E [s],canbecalculatedusingtheprobability n L H densityfunctionfromthisexpression,whichleadsto (cid:90) CnVL (cid:18) n−C (cid:18) n (cid:19)(cid:19) E [s]= sf (s)ds= 1− ln V (6) H H C n−C L 0 Toexpressthisresultintermsofexpectedprices,wefindthat (cid:16) (cid:16) (cid:17)(cid:17) E [P ]=V − 1− n−C ln n V . H H H C n−C L 9 DECK,C.,A.FARMERANDJ.FOSTER Similarly,theexpectedprofittoH forofferingasurplusofsis F (s)[(V −s)C−K C]+(1−F (s))[−K C]. (7) L H C L C ThesecurityprofitforH isdeterminedbythegreatestpriceH cansetandnotgetundercutby L,whichwaspreviouslydeterminedtobeP = V − CV . Usingthispricetodeterminethe H H n L security profit for H we find Πs = (cid:0)V − CV −K (cid:1)C. Equating (7) to Πs and solving for H H n L C H F (s)wefind L V − CV F (s)= H n L (8) L V −s H wheres∈(cid:2)0,CV (cid:3). CalculatingL’sexpectedsurpluswefind n L E [s]=(cid:90) CnVLsf (s)ds= CV −(cid:18)V − CV (cid:19)ln(cid:32) VH (cid:33) (9) L L n L H n L V − CV 0 H n L Thus,theexpectedpriceofLcanbeexpressedas EL[PL]=(cid:0)1− Cn(cid:1)VL+(cid:0)VH − CnVL(cid:1)ln(cid:16)VH−VHCnVL(cid:17). 1.1.3 Stage1: HighQualitySellerSetsInventory Finally,inconsiderationofstage1behaviorweseektheinventoryCthatmaximizesH’sex- pectedprofit. Giventhemixedstrategyinpricing,thisisequivalenttomaximizingitssecurity profit, ΠsH = (cid:0)VH − CnVL−KC(cid:1)C. Therefore C∗ = min(cid:110)n2VHV−LKC,C(cid:111). Table 1 summarizes theexpectedpricesandprofitstobothsellersasH’sstage1capacitydecision, C, changesfor aparticularsetofparameters. Theseparametervaluesarethesameasthoseusedinthelabo- ratory experiments described in the next section. In particular we set n = 6, C = 5, K = 3, C V =15,andV =9. FromTable1itisclearthatwiththeseparameters,C∗ =4. H L Table1: ExpectedPricesandProfitsforδ =1 C P∗ Π∗ P∗ Π∗ H H L L 1 14.2 10.5 8.9 45 2 13.3 18 8.7 36 3 12.2 22.5 8.3 27 4 10.9 24 7.6 18 5 9.2 22.5 6.7 9 COMPETITIVEMARKETSWHENCUSTOMERSANTICIPATESTOCKOUTS 10 AsummaryofCase1predictionsovershopperandsellerbehaviorisprovidedasResult1 below. Result1.Whenitiscostlessforshopperstoexperienceastockout,shoppersfollowapurestrat- egyandbothsellerspursueamixedstrategyoverthepricestheycharge.Further,theinventory ofthehighqualitysellermaybelessthanorequaltotheircapacityconstraint. Formally, 1 ifVH −PH ≥VL−PL λ∗ = 0 otherwise n−C s F (s)= H C V −s (10) L V − CV F (s)= H n L L V −s H (cid:26) (cid:27) nV −K C∗ =min H C,C . 2 V L 1.2 Case2: ConsumersFaceAProhibitivelyCostlyStockout(δ = 0) 1.2.1 Stage3: ShoppersMakePurchasingDecisions In this case, the condition for a shopper to find it optimal to pursue {H,∅} rather than {L,∅}isp(λ|C,Q)(V −P )>V −P . Giventhesymmetry,ifthisshopperfindsitoptimal H H L L tovisitH thentheQ = n−1othershopperswillalsofinditoptimalandthechancethatany particular shopper is not stocked out is C. This implies that when V −P < C(V −P ), n L L n H H λ∗ =1. Whenp(λ|C,Q)(V −P )=V −P ashopperisindifferentbetween{H,∅}and{L,∅} H H L L andthereisamixedstrategyequilibrium. Toidentifythemixedstrategyequilibriumonemust expresspasafunctionofλ,C,andQasin(11). C−1(cid:18) (cid:19) Q (cid:18) (cid:19) (cid:88) Q (cid:88) C Q p(λ|C,Q)= λm(1−λ)Q−m+ λm(1−λ)Q−m (11) m m+1 m m=0 m=C (cid:124) (cid:123)(cid:122) (cid:125) (cid:124) (cid:123)(cid:122) (cid:125) Pr(m<C)⇒ Pr(m≥C)⇒ ReceivesItematH RandomlyReceivesItematH The first summation in (11) represents the probability that H does not stock out. The second summation in (11) represents the probability that the shopper is able to buy the item from H whenthereisastockout. Theindexvariablemisthenumberofothershopperswhoattempt
Description: