Recently published: COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM A Study in Judicial Interpretation by VICTOR S. MACKINNON M.A., LL.B. (Glas8OW,) LL. M., SID. (Harvard) Senior Lecturer in Comparative Constitutional Law, University of Edinburgh FOREWORD BY ARTHUR E. SUTHERLAND Harvard Law School MAR TINUS NIJHOFF / THE HAGUE MAR TINUS NIJHOFF - PUBLISHER - THE HAGUE The underlying premiss of this book is that a constitution is something more than a set of procedural rules. Rather, it should be viewed as an organic creation, as a point of departure, and not merely a description of a status quo which is to be maintained. The role of judicial interpretation and application of basic texts is a crucial one to this dynamic function. In federal systems the judicial branch is frequently charged with the task of reviewing exercises oflegislative power, federal and state, in the light of whether that legislation impairs a balance between economic freedom of competition, the protection of local state autonomy, and a measure of national uniformity. The author endeavours to show that in all systems where similar such objectives can be identified, then, while the terms of their respective constitutions may shape the methods of judicial reasoning under them, they do not necessarily dictate the solutions reached. These several but similar objectives will be reflected in similar solutions to problems encountered by all, irrespective of differences in political structure and functioning among those systems, and irrespective also of terminological differences in the expression of the basic consti tutional texts as to grants of power and limitations on power. These arguments are developed and illustrated by means of a compara tive analysis of a major problem of federalism, viz., the regulation and taxation of trade and commerce among the Member States of a federal union. The systems selected for study are those of the United States of America, Canada, and Australia, whose experience the author believes to have substantial background relevance for all federal countries and, in particular, to the emerging problems of the European Communities. About the author: Born 1928. Studied at the University of Glasgow (M.A., LL.B.). After a period of practice as a Solicitor in Scotland, engaged in further study at the Harvard Law School. (LL. M., S. f. D.) He is now Senior Lecturer in Comparative Consti tutional Law in the University of Edinburgh. 1964. XXVII and 188 pages. Guilders 21.40 MARTINUS NIJHOFF - PUBLISHER - THE HAGUE M. F. Anabtawi, Arab unity in terms oflaw. 1963. XIV and 263 pages. Guilders 18.- Annuaire Europeen / European Yearbook. Publie sous les auspices du Consei1 de l'Europe / Published under the auspices of the Council of Europe. Comite de redaction / Editorial Committee: M. Ludovico Benvenuti, M. W. Cornides, Sylvain Frey, B. Landheer, Donald Mallett, Codacci Pisanelli, J. E. Rabier, A. H. Robertson and Max S0rensen. Secretaires du Comite de redaction / Joint editors: B. Landheer and W. Horsfall Carter. I. 1955. XXV and 584 pages. Out of print II. 1956. XX and 727 pages. Cloth guilders 35.- III. 1957. XIX and 534 pages. Cloth guilders 25.50 IV. 1958. XXI and 708 pages. Cloth guilders 37.50 V. 1959. XIX and 755 pages. Cloth guilders 41.- VI. 1959. XV and 530 pages. Cloth guilders 31.- VII. 1960. XIX and 800 pages. Cloth guilders 49.75 VIII. 1961. XVII and 793 pages. Cloth guilders 49.75 IX. 1962. XVII and 859 pages. Cloth guilders 57.- X. 1963. 2 vols. I: XXV and 695 pages; II: pp. 696-1293. Together cloth guilders 95.- Arbitrage International CODlDlercial / International CODl Dlercial Arbitration. Rapporteur general Pieter Sanders. I. 1956. 483 pages. Cloth guilders 27.50 = Western Europe, U.S.A. II. 1960. XI and 400 pages. Cloth guilders 26.50 =Latin America, Eastern Europe; New York Arbitration Conference 1958, Arbi- tration Rules V. D. Degan, L'interpretation des accords en droit international. 1963. XI and 176 pages. Guilders 16.20 Robert B. Ellert, Nato 'Fair Trial' safeguards. Precursor to an international bill of procedural rights. 1963. VI and 89 pages. Guilders 9.40 Werner Feld, The court of the European communities: New di mension in international adjudication. 1964. VIII and 127 pages. Guilders 13.50 MARTINUS NIjHOFF - PUBLISHER - THE HAGUE Ezzeldin Foda, The projected Arab court of justice. A study in regional jurisdiction with specific reference to the Muslim law of nations. Presentation by A. H. Badawi. 1957. XVI and 258 pages. Cloth guilders 19.- Marek St. Korowicz, Introduction to international law. Present conceptions of intemationallaw in theory and practice. Second impression. 1964. IX and 424 pages. Guilders 35.- Pierre Mathijsen, Le droit de la Communaute Europeenne du Charbon et de l'A cier. U ne etude des sources. 1958. 208 pages Guilders 12.- Maung Maung, Burma's constitution. Second revised edition. With a foreword by J. S. Furnivall. 1961. XX and 340 pages. With 18 plates. Guilders 23.50 Amos J. Peaslee and Dorothy Peaslee Xydis, International governmental organizations. Constitutional documents. Revised second edition. 1961. 2 vols. I : LVIII and 922 pp. ; II: XVI and 1039 pages Together cloth guilders 82.50 J. J. G. Syatauw, Some newly established Asian states and the development ofinternationallaw. 1961. XII and 249 pages. With 2 maps, 1 folding map and 1 table. Guilders 19.- One guilder = abo $ 0.278 = ab 2 sb = eDV. Fr. 1.36 =-ca. DMW 1.10 Obtainable through any bookseller or direct from the publisher COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM A Study in Judicial Interpretation by VICTOR S. MACKINNON M.A., LL.B. (Glasgow), LL.M., S.l.D. (Harvard) Senior Lecturer in Comparative Constitutional Law, University 0/ Edinburgh FOREWORD BY ARTHUR E. SUTHERLAND Harvard Law School • THE HAGUE MARTINUS NIJHOFF 1964 To My Parents ISBN 978-94-011-823 7-9 ISBN 978-94-011-8910-/ (eBook) 001 10.1007/978-94-01 J --89/0-1 Copyright I964 by Martinus Nijhott, The Hagu~. Netherlands All rights reserved, i.ncluding the right to. trans/ale 0" to. reprodllce this book or parts thereof in any form FOREWORD Modem societies, - like organized societies of all eras, - suffer from antithetical aspirations, from competing institutionalizations of that which is desirable, and that which, though unwelcome, is inevitable. Men clearly see the advantages of localism, of the self determination of small peoples, of l' amour du chocher uninhibited by imperial sovereign ty. At the same time men everywhere are seeing the clear necessity of bigness in organization of national effort. When the question is military organization no one has much doubt that strength derives from power ful union. The Swiss, to be sure, have continued independent not because of their power, but because of the convenience of their in dependent existence. In a world-society of titans, there must be members who are small, respected, independent and unfeared, available to be intermediaries. If Switzerland did not exist, it would have been necessary to invent her. But the power centers are those with the big battalions and the megatons of bombs; both demand great aggregates. Tomorrow's military power structure is calculated in the hundreds of millions of people. The world will afford only a few Switzerlands. The drive toward bigness is as inevitable in the economic world as in that of destructive machines. Economic problems in the next century, and in the next after it, will require the concentrated re sources of the nations; we must produce adequate food for the billions, or else billions will war against billions. We must organize the immense energies required to turn the salt water of seas into the sweet waters of civilization, or millions will die of drought. The prototype reconciliation of local autonomy with the necessity of major organization was that of the United States in I787. Its difficulties have been many; federalism is not a self-evident process. Its political theory was as simple, however, as its implementation has been complex. Let us, we said, decide what things are necessarily done by VI FOREWORD great aggregates of people, and what, on the other hand, are suitable for local whim. Let us then write in a great charter a description of that which will be done by the national many, and that which will be left to the local few. In this way, we thought, we shall have the best of two possible worlds. In the United States we early found out that our constitutional words were not as universally resolving as we had hoped. To allot economic power among the thirteen commonwealths of our fledgling nation, our formula was to ascribe to the aggregate government "commerce with foreign nations and among the several States," saving all the rest of our economic life to our local entities. At once we found out that even our simple pioneer society was too complex thus to divide into clearly separate functions. What was local sometimes also seemed like that which was national; local events had national repercussions, making national control unavoidable. Fortunately, we had invented a governmental institution which provided a means of arbitrating such innumerable interstitial questions of federal existence. Dedicated as we were to the ideal of electoral majoritarianism, we nevertheless had created an appointive Supreme Court, constitutionally exempted from the compulsions of popularity. Much as we paid lip service to a simple concept of frontier egalitarianism, to the converti bility of any honest man for another, here we set up, secure for life, an intellectual judicial governing elite. To this extraordinary body we entrusted the umpiring of the federal system, the case-by-case decision of what in our economy should be local, and what should be national. As the world has developed in the century-and-three-quarters since 1787, more and more people have discovered the possibilities, - perhaps the somewhat illusory possibilities, - of federal structure. Illusory or not, "federalism" has become increasingly popular; and with it has necessarily grown the prevalence of an institution like the Supreme Court of the United States. Dr. Victor MacKinnon in this volume has given us a philosophical analysis of the intellectual and of the pragmatic operation of such courts in Canada, in Australia, and in the United States. Wisely, he has inscribed on his introductory page Mr. Justice Johnson's conclusion a century and a half ago that "half the doubts in life arise from the defects of language"; one only wonders why the Justice limited his proportion to such a small share. For as the author shows us, in each of the federal unions he analyzes, although the language in the con stituent document of each allots some functions to nation and some to the several component political units, the judges in each have dis- FOREWORD VII covered that the analytical process of interpreting this language, - that the substantive problems which underlie superficial clarity of words, - turn out to be much the same regardless of the differing verbal for mulations in the several constituent charters. In pursuit of his analysis of these constructional processes, Dr. MacKinnon has followed his national tradition of the close analysis of specific cases. He has studied more than three hundred and seventy opinions of the Privy Council, of the highest courts of Australia, Canada, and of the United States. He explores the difficulties of describing that portion of the economy which is essentially national, in contrast to that which is essentially local. He scrutinizes the differ ence, theoretical rather than practical, between national "regulation" and national "prohibition." He turns the lens of an intellectual microscope on the difference between that which is local and that which is national in the process of manufacture. He examines a series of such problems which alike in the three nations which make up his subject matter, have arisen to plague the courts which ultimately pass upon the division of governing functions in their respective countries. The reader who studies Dr. MacKinnon's work would make a mistake if he limited his consideration to its value solely as a work of historical analysis. In a world of increasing economic complexity and inter relation, some form of organization resembling the federal structure of Australia, of Canada, or of the United States, is quite likely to grow up among large groups of nations now discrete. The Common Market in Europe follows the pattern of growth of federal union on the North Atlantic seaboard between 1755 and 1789, not because of imitation, but out of the sheer necessity of societal growth. In Africa and in Asia new federal unions are appearing. The federal plan is, for our time, the probable pattern of future national aggregates. Thus Dr. MacKinnon's book is a prediction of things to come. The philosopher of political organization will do well to read the lessons implicit in his scholarly exposition. ARTHUR E. SUTHERLAND Cambridge, Massachusetts March, 1964.
Description: