ebook img

CHAPTER 9 Mathemati.cal Anthropology - Eclectic Anthropology PDF

78 Pages·2003·58.07 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview CHAPTER 9 Mathemati.cal Anthropology - Eclectic Anthropology

From Handbook of S:lclal and Cultural Anthropt)& logy. John J. Honlgmann, Ed. Copyright 1974 by Rand McNally College Publlshlna Complll11. All r1aht. re rved. 9 Mathemati.cal Anthropology CHAPTER DOUGLAS R. WHITE INTRODUCTION of the problems currently modeled by mathematics are of such general rele This review will introduce the gener vance to anthropological theory that it al reader in anthropology to some of is doubtful that they should be con the uses of mathematics in the analysis fined under the title of mathematical of ethnographic data in order to inten anthropology. What unites them under sify the conceptual and explanatory this rubric is not quantification, which power of anthropological theory. Many covers a fraction of mathematics, but rather the common logical substructure Early drafts of various sections of this paper were reviewed and criticized by others, and I have tried to that mathematics shares with science in incorporate their criticisms and to interpret the ex the use of axiomatic reasoning. The I tensive work that has been done in mathematical major thrust of modern mathematical anthropology in light of various suggestions. I grate~ thought has been to refine the logical fully acknowledge the assistance and encouragement of William Geoghegan, Paul Kay, Robert Randall, underpinnings of mathematical systems fran«ois Lorrain, Michael Agar, Robert Kozelka, of analysis. Thomas Fararo, Ira Buchler, and Michael Burton, and the critical and editorial suggestions of G. P. example from his unpublished work on kinship alge Murdock and Lilyan Brudner. I am also grateful to bra. My professors at the University of Minnesota .. E. A. Kimball Romney, Roy G. D'Andrade, George Adamson Hoebel, Pertti J. Pelto, and Eldin Johnson, Collier, Kenneth Morgan, and Bob Scholte for sugges contributed encouragement to the exploration of tions, contributions, and references, lind to members mathematical anthropology; professors in mathe of the Summer Seminar in Quantitative Anthropol matical psychology at the University of Michigan, ogy for (1!scussions that stimulated illY thinking on including Clyde CoombS, Frank Harary, Louis Gutt the general subject. man, James Lingoes, and Robert Hefner, provided an G. P. Murdock was particularly helpful in pro important part of my training. viding information on the Natchez case, Ira Buchler provided the stimulus for the Kapauku analysis, Wil I In the twentieth century, modern mathemati liam Geoghegan provided the solution to the Purum cians have shown that all mathematics is based upon case and generously wen t over his field rna terial on axiomatic reasoning in which four basic concepts are the Samai address system, and Robert Randall gra involved: (I) a specific.ation of primitive notions; (2) ciously allowed me to use the American kin-terms a presentation of relevant definitions built up from 369 370 DOUG LAS R. WH ITE Axiomatic reasoning is central not portant types of general anthropologi only to mathema tics bu t also to the cal problems that are modeled. growth and development of modern This review examines theoretical sciences. It provides a logical skeleton contributions of mathematical anthro upon which systems of explanation and pology in (l) processllaL analysis (2) veri fica tion are constructed. A mod eI optimization analysis (3) structural derive·d fl~om an axiomatil- theory con analysis (graph theory) and (4) ethno tains a logical structure of ,quival nce graphic decomposition. Other areas of between the et of axioms and the s t mathematization in anthropology, such of consequences derived from the as data reduction through matrix and axioms. An interpretation of such a statistical analysis, and inferential gen model with respect to a body of data eralization through statistical analysis allows logical explanation> such that if and inference will not be discussed an axiom set is true, a consequence set her . These om issions are d u partly to derived from it must also be. true (i.e., limitations of spa e and pm·tly to the logjcal extension from known facts), fact that these ar as are higllly devel and a1 0 allows in lire.ct fal ification oped and their anthropological applica such that if tJle cons quence set con tions are therefore better known than tains a false stat m nt, the. axiom set the Val·joLls topics I shall be discussing cannot be true (i.e., indi.rect invalida (but see Burton 1970 and Romney, tion of first premises). Axiomatic Shepard and Nerlove 1972 on new de models differ from the conventional velopments in scaling theory).2 and looser use of the teflTl ' lnodel" in The four types of mathematical social science research. The latter usage modeling that will be discussed) viewed provides no formal system of explana in conjunction provide a framework tion and falsification, since here the for explanatory theories of ~)ehavior in term "lnoder' refers simply to an anal relation to anthropological data. Pro ogous relationship between one phe cessuaJ analysis and optimization anal- nomenon and another. ysis focus on the development of theo In tllis review we shall be concerned lies and models of social process. The with models in the narrower sense processual models (section 1) dea l with models derived from mathematizecl axiomatic theory. Rather than attempt to trace the developments that encour 2 Previous reviews 3(ld readings on mathematical anthropology can roughly be divided into six cate aged the Ll e of .mathematicaJ reason gories with selected refert:nces. as follows: ing in an thropology the present frarne 1-2. Processua\ and optimization ;;1nalysis (Buchler of reference is designed to allow the and Selby 1968a, Buchler and Nutini 1969 resultant accomplishments to represent Buchler and Kozelka n.d.). themselves and be judged largely on 3, StTU tural analysis (graph theory) (l3arnes 1969, Flarncnt 1963). their own merits. The FraIne of reference 4, Algebraic or ethnographic decomposition is organized in terms of severa] i111- (White 1963· Hoffmann L970 (gen"ral re view article]; Kay, ed.. 1971 i also includes items under 5 and 6)). the primjtives; (3) a statement of axioms containing 5. Quantification statistics, probability (Mitch only primitives and auxiliary definitions; and (4) log ell 1963. 1967; Hammel and Fwedman n.eI.; icaJ derivation of tilcorems from t.he preceding ele Driver 1953,1961, 1965; D'Andrade 1959). ments, stich th~t if the a~il)ms are tmc, the theorems 6. Data redu tion via matrix analysis and com necessa.rily follow (for a rigorous anthropological ex pnter analysis (Bu rton 1970; Rornney, Shep ample see Geoghegan 1971; for an earlier use of the ar{l, and Nerlove t972· Hymes. ed., 1965). logicodeductive or postulational method, see Mur Only items I through 4 are jncluded in tile present dock 1949). review. MATHEMATICAL ANTHROPOLOGY 371 the limits and contingencies of social social forms. The need for a generative systems, providing a quantitative and approach to social organization and somewhat mechanistic model of a behav structure was suggested by Murdock ioral system. The optimization models (1955) and others, and articulated 111 (section 2) add the element of goal greater detail by Barth (1966:2):3 directed behavior, broadening proces sual analysis to include choice and Patterns are generated through processes of learning behavior. Structural analysis interaction and in their form reflect the can· and ethnographic decomposition begin straints and incentives under which people act. I hold that this transformation from con· with theories of modeling data by axi straints and incentives to frequentative pat· omatic methods. They search for pat terns of behavior in a population is complex tern, structure, and regularity in ethno~ but has a structure of its own, and that by an graphic data, translating insight about understanding of it we shall be able to explain structural properties of anthropological numerous features of social form. Indeed ... data into formal axiomatic structures. the processes which effect that transformation Structural analysis through graph theo are our main field of study as social anthropol· ry (section 3) is useful in developing ogists. models of structural properties, and in examining the fit between these theo In this section we shall examine the retical principles and complex bodies of uses of mathematical models in the in data about empirical structures. Eth vestigation of social processes, focusing nographic decomposition (section 4) ap chiefly on the problems of relating the plies primarily to the qualitative and principles of social behavior at the indi sY111bolic areas of rule systems in cul vidual level (residence, marriage align ture, including rules of appropriateness, ment, recruitment to social groups, ac ordering rules, decision rules, transfor ceptance of innovation, etc.) to social mation rules, and the like. Structural forms and frequencies of behavior at analysis and ethnographic decomposi the group level. The social processes are tion, as part of an integrated approach mediated by a large number of contin to data analysis, provide a basis on gencies. Numbers of people in the sys- which theoretical statements about human behavior can be constructed, se 3 Murdock (J 955: 361), for example, stated: "However useful, and indeed indispensable, is ihis cure in both empirical adequacy and a lask of claSSification, it is by no means the ultimate seIt-consistent logical structure. Proces goal of science. Any typological system is, by its sual and optimization analysis provide a very nature, siatic in character. It takes on full more general and theoretical account of meaning only when scientists are able to demon· sociocultural and behavioral systems. strate the dynamic processes which give rio e to the phenomena thus classified. The Linnaean system, for example, came alive only afler Darwin had discerned rhe processes of variation and natural selection, and I. PROCESSUAL ANALYSIS especially after the geneticists had laid bare the dy· Social anthropology is concerned namic mechanisms of heredity." with explaining similarity and diversity Simila.rly, Barth (1966:2) stated: "Explanation (of social formsl is not achieved by a description of forms of social life. The focus on of patterns of regularity, no matter how meticulous explanation in anthropology, which and adequate, liar by replacing this description by builds lipan and supersedes description other abstractions congruent with it, but by exhibit· and classification, represents a shift ing what makes the pat tern, i.e., certain prOcesses. To study social forms, it is certainly necessa.ry but from the study of forms of soeiallife to hardly sufficient to be able to describe them. To th investigation of the generative rela give an explanation of social forms, it is suffiCient to tionship between social processes and describe the prOcesses that generate the form."' 372 DOlJGLAS R. WHITE tern (i.e., delnographic factors), distri difference equa tions). Compu tel' simula bution of resources (e.g.) ecological and tions provide a mathernatical model economic factors), and other contin through mllnerical computation when a gencies mitigate the effect of cultural generat mathematical so1ution to a prob rules or indiv id ual lnotives and stra te len) is not already worked out. Simula- gies. They constitute the fnHnework or tions may be either probabilistic or de ground rutes within which a social sys terministic. A decision tree may also tem operates (Buchler and Selby be used as a processual model if a pop 1968a). The study of social process can ulation (defi.ned in tern1S of variable be viewed from the perspective of sta situations of individuals within it) is tistical factors in demography) resource "mapped" by the tree into a set of out distribution, situations, etc.> or [raIn conles. Tills model Inay again be either the perspective of the interaction be cletenninlstic or pro ba bi.listic, depend tween statistical factors and cultural or ing on whether the outcomes are certain jural rules. or probable. Until recently there was no foun In cOIllparison to a body of ethno dation in anthropology for a systematic graphic data, axiomatic mathematical investigation of vaTious types of social theories and derived models provide a process. Earlier processual accounts much greater number of theoretical for example, of marriage systems-"had possibilities than are contailled in a few theoretically determined base lines finite bocly of data. The data used to from whiCh to draw conclusions regard test various models may be statistical ing the differential effect of ecolog distributions or observations over time. icat~ demographic, and cultural varia The nlodels may be tested at those tions on social organization~' (Gilbert points where data are available, but and Han1mel 1966:72). Recently, they may also help clarify other areas Inathematical Inodels, including com." of the theoretical problem for future pl1ter SDnulatlol1, have provided the research. They may serve as a guide to needed framework for the analysis of the collect jon of new data needed to interactions between c01l1plex sets of test and refine the theory or model. variables. These models have been This provides the research with a para applied to problems such as residential digmatic quality (Kuhn 1962), in that patterns, marriage choice, recruitment past, present, and future data can be patterns, and diffusion of infofl11ation related to a. formal model or theory, as wen as material artefacts. Formal and findings can feed back to mod ify theories pertinen t to these phenolnena the general theoretica1 framework. aJlow models to be derived which can In the choice of a model for a theo be compared with actual ethnographic ry, the distinction between pro babilis data. The criterion of a well-formed tic and deterministic models is iJnpor theory in such cases is the extent to tant and should be understood. Deter wltich a logical stnh"ture of explanation ministic systems, exemplified by New of the process is provided, and how ton's laws, aSSUlne that the entire well the mode} of the theory can ma tch future of the system can be predicted actual cia tao given sufficient infonnation about the Mathematical models that may be past. Probahilistlc systems, such as sta utilized in pJocessual analysis include tistical mechanics, can predict only the the probabilistic (e.g., stochastic or probabilities of certain future occur time-dependent statistical processes) rences (Kemeny and Snell 1962: 5), and the detenninistic (e.g., linear or usually becoming tess accurate as the MATHFMATICAL ANTHROPOLOGY 373 time span lengthens. Probabilistic mod abilities. Finite state probability mod els arc suited to a host of contingency els have only recently begun to be used factors that play important parts in so in anthrop.ology but th y havc proved cial processes. De term inistic models useful in relation to questions of change come into play either as approximations and stability, and in the analysis of un of the probability model (e.g., exact cal intended consequences of social pro culation of the most likely or expected cesses. outcome) or else as an approximate Buchler and Selby (l968a:58-68) representation of a set of cultural rules. have suggcsted that studies of devel It is highly unlikely that the social sci opmental cycles and change in residen ences will ever approach deterministic tial patterns can benefit from stochastic laws in the Newtonian sense of strict modeling. Residential patterns were prediction. As we shall see, deter one of the first ethnographiL: phenom ministic models that do take social con ena to be modeled processually (see tingencies into accollnt and may pre Fortes 1945, 1949). Fortes' work stim dict behavior very accurately at a given ulated others (e.g., Mitchell 1956, point in time have been developed; Smith 1956) to study resid ntial pat these models will not, however, explain terns developmentally in terms of change in the system- that is, they do ho useho Id compositio n. The emphasis not predict well over time. The closer on process also led to new conceptual we come to an exact model of the interests in decision pro cesses under structure of social behavior, the less we lying residential choice (Goodenough m'e able to ac 'ollnt for change, and the 1956b). more \VC are able to deal with change A major problem in the devel (e.g., through probabilities) the less opmental studies of residence and of exact our knowledge of the structure. household affiliation and composition There is thus no possibility (or human (e.g., Goocly,ed., 1958,HammeI1961, istic "danger"") of reducing human be Fortes 1962, and Miller 1964 for the havior to a set of mathematical pre former; Fisch r 1958, Barnes 1960, and dictions, although mathematics may Romney n.d. for the latter) was in help to make both process and struc ga uging the eff 'cts of vital ra tes, repro ture understandable as aspects of ductive ages, segmentation processes, human behavior. A review of anthro and so forth on household composi pological uSeS of proc ssual mathe tion. A stochastic model can, in effect, matical models may show the potential ha ndle all of these factors sirl'l ul complementarity of probabilistic and taneously by setting appropriate transi deterministic models. tion probabilities for household compo sition types over time. Buchler and Selby (1968a :63-66) show how such a A. PROBABILISTIC MODELS model could be constructed using the Stocha~tic 01' probabilistic approxi example of Freeman's (1958) data on mation models represent one of the the Iban bilek famjly system. If the modern developments in statistics, ill various demographic factors are rela the statistical modeling of empirical tively constant over time, it is possible phenomena. In a processual model, or to assume that the transition probabili stochastic process, a phenomenon is ties representing the normal frequencies represented as a set of tates that are of maintenance and change in house maintained over time or altered in ac hold types are also constan t. A stochas cordance with a set of transition protr tic process with stable transition prob- 374 DOUGLAS R. WHITE abilities, called a Markov process, has and has disrupted this cycle: young an important Inathen1atical property: it men and women move off the island can be proved that the expected fre for wage labor, al1d often send their quencies in successive states of the sys children back to be cared for by grand tem, as cornputed by the transition parents. In comparing two sllccessive probabilities, approach a limiting set of censuses (1961 and 1968), Otterbein values or an equilibrium vector. Regard found that the actual patterns of main less of the initial set of frequencies of tenance or change in household com the systen1, the same limiting vector position differed considerably from the will be reached for a given matrix of normative developmental cycle in the transition probabilities. I shall attempt past. The types and nun1bers of changes to illustrate a Inathematical model of can be indicated in a finite-state dia such a system using Otterbein's (1970) gram (Figure 2). The numbers to the data on J"esidence changes on Andros rjght of the diagram indicate formation Island. of new families and dissolution of old Otterbein (1970: 1414) has classified families (new/old). Andros Island households into nine In spite of the small numbers in this types. These have been relabeled in sample, the frequencies of stability and Figure 1 to show basic family types and change give a fairly accurate indication their composition in tenns of principal of the relative frequency or probability adult menlbers. The anows on the dia of the transition processes during the gram indicate the traditional develop seven-year period. The transit jon prob mental cycle from a married couple ability matrix can be computed for (Z2) to a nuclear fan1i1y (X2) to an these data to show transitions for the extended family (Y2), followed by a three types of families (nuclear, extend- decline of the faInily; typically the ed, adult) as well as for the category grandfather dies first (leaving type Y D, which stands for the demographic 1 ), and finally the children and grand processes of formation of new house children move away> leaving the grand holds from the delnographic pool of mother alone (Zl ). Migration from the Unn1alTied adults, etc. (D!), and dissolu island, however, has been increasing, tion of households through death or Basic Family Types Principal Nuclear Extended Adult (with (with Adults Demogl'aphic f11embers Children) Grandchildren) Only Factors Dissolution Female XI YI > 2\ )- by death or 1 migration Couple X2 ) Y2 ~Z2( Formation of ~ new famiHes Male X3 Y Z3 3 Figure 1. Normal developmental cycle among household types in traditional Andros society. MATHEMATICAL ANTHROPOLOGY 375 Frequency data: Numbers of households of To: later time period each type. X Y Z Dd XI X2 X3 YI YZ Y3 ZI Z2 Z3 Ftirmoem :p eeraiorldie r XY 00..50 00..36 00..20 00..22 1961 4 25 I 9 15 2 II 8 10 Z 0.0 0.1 0.4 0.5 1968 4 17 a II 20 I 7 5 8 Df 0.5 0.5 0.0 0.0 Diagram: Transitions for the nine household We sec from the matrix, for example, types, including demographic factors of for that there is an 0.5 probability that a ma tion and dissolution of households. type X household in 1961 will remain so in 1968, an 0.3 probability that it DIIDd x will change to type Y, 0.0 to type Z, Y Z (formation/dissolution) and 0.2 that it will disappear. If these G -2-0 transition probabilities are stable, the _2_Y 2 3/1 4/3 1/7 1 I 3/; I ·2- I same will be true for any seven-year "0/,q:::l;). period in the future. 3/4 1/1 0/1 Given the matrix, the operation of 11 '2,,! the stochastic (Markov) process on a I -1-'E)4 X3 l3 0/1 J/O 0/6 population for successive time intervals can be illustrated_ We will start with a hypothetical population of eighty household s in 1961, plus a pool of Reduc_e_d_ _st_a t1e- -d..i.a.g,.r.a m: potential householders (category D, which also in this hypothetical case 1s Ct-8--cY:;::~~-?' 6/6 5/4 1/14 represents the number of out-migrants), 16 12 distributed to correspond to the census data figures fo l' 1961 for the household types X, Y, and Z. We shall assume that Reduced state matrix the numbers for the various types of (corresponding to reduced stale diagram: families in 1961 are X = 28, Y = 25, Z '" 27, and that in category D there are 20 x Y Z Dd potential households. The expected val ues for household distributions for X 15 8 I 6 a 1968 can then be computed, for exam Y 16 6 4 Z a 3 12 14 ple: a Df 6 5 1 X(l968) = O.5X( 19(1) + 0.OY(l961) Figure 2. Construction of transition matrix + O.OZ( 1961) + O.SD( 1961) = 0.5 x 28 + D.5 x 20 from Andros household censuses for 1961 = 14 + 10" 24 and 1968. The equilibrium vector can be com migration (Dd)_ The approximate tran puted by solving a set of linear equa sition probabilities, computed from the tions where X, Y, Z, and D have the reduced state matrix in Figure 2, are as same value before and after transitional follows: probabilities are computed. The values 376 DOUGLAS R. WHITE at successive time intervals can then be same cycle or set of grades as their compared with the final equilibrium fathers (Hoffmann 1965, 1971). In the values: Shoa Galla system, for example, in which the age-grade cycle is forty 1961 1968 1975 1982 ... Equilibrium years long (five grades at eight-year x 28 24 24 22 20 intervals), stability would represent a y 25 36 42 44 45 problem if the age span between father Z 27 16 14 14 ]5 and son were much less or much greater D 20 24 20 20 20 than forty years.4 Hoffmann's (1971) assumption that a Markov pro cess model is applicable to this case is q ues The equilibriu111 point (20, 45) 15) tionable, because the transition prob 20) will be the same regardless of the abilities cannot be assumed to approx initial frequencies. In this case, the imate stability. On the contrary, the initial frequencies, after two intervals, likelihood of a son's entering his fa lead to expected values that approach ther's grade at the same age as his father within 4 percent of the equilibrium did obviously depends on the age of the vector and are in three intervals within father when the son was born. 2 per~ent of equilibrium values. Thus, Unless the conditions for the use of whereas the past domestic cycle on stochastic or Markov models are ful Andros Island may have involved a low filled (i.e., satisfaction of the assump percentage of extended families (e.g., tions of the axioms of the model and about 20 percent), the new conditions nonarbitrary detennination of transi would stabilize within fifteen years, tion probabilities), the use of these when the frequency of extended falni models simply replicates initial faulty lies approaches 45 percent. By the use assumptions without providing better of the stochastic model, then, aspects understanding of the mechanisms in of processes of stability and change can volved. The decision to use a stochastic be evaluated more precisely. As Buchler or Markov process model should be and Selby (19680.:67) state: based upon the plausibility of assunip tions that can be made about the phe This perspective opens up a variety of nomenon being modeled, and, as far as approaches and poses a series of questions its predictive adequacy is concerned, relevant to pro cess and change. Consider one on the extent to which (1) the actual example: residence rules. We may sa~ that .a given society is «matrilocal," typo!ogtze~esl­ dential processes (Fischer 1958), or conSlder the decision processes underlying residential 4 This is an example of the more widespread choice (Goodenough 1956b). But . .. it is of Gada, or cycling, system i.n North Africa (Murdock considerable importance to construct and 1959: 326). Entrance into the system is crucial for examine a transition rna trix in order to deter~ adult status, so stability of the system is a rea1 mll1e the stability of the . . . tendency, to question. compute a limiting vector that may well indi~ Hoffmann (1965, 1971) shows that stability of the system can be expressed in an equation, where cate a drift .... Here, then, is a new way of Dn is defined as the difference in age at entry of a coming at the problem of process. descendant "11" generations hence, the length of the cycle is denoted by "k" (in this case, forty years), and the average reproductive age by "P." Then Dn = Equilibrium conditions in a Markov n· k- ~ p .. If P is greater them 40, D n is negative; if process model have also been used to i I . analyze age-grade systems of the type P js less than 40, Dn is positive. The system Will be stable only when Dr! = 0, which occurs when P is in which sons must go through the equal to 40. MATHEMATICAL ANTHROPOLOGY 377 transition probabilities can be logically mel developed a formal mathematical derived or estimated from known data model of the probability of cousin mar and (2) the model can be tested against riages as a function of the probability time-sequence data for goodness of fit. of endogamous marriage, and they were Marriage choice is another area of able to compare the results of the two traditional anthropological interest that models.5 The close fit between the has only recently been studied proces formal mathematical model and the sually. Models of marriage choice phe computer simulation tended to confirm nomena within cultural, social, and the conceptual validity of each. demographic constraints are so com Models of the type used by Gilbert plex as to require mathematical treat and Hammel can be adapted to similar ment. This represents the first major studies in other societies. Variables area in anthropology in which com such as territorial marriage preferences, puter simulation has been used (Kun residence rules, and demographic fac stadter et al. 1963; Coult and Hammel tors can be changed without affecting 1963; Randolph and CouIt 1968; Gil the basic structure of the problem, so bert and Hammel 1965, 1966), al that their effects upon expected mar though later refinements have made use riage frequencies may be observed. of stochastic processes as well (Morgan Through the use of experimental mod 1969, 1970). In general, the operation els (probabilistic equations and simu and consequences of a cultural rule or lations) it is possible to examine rela marriage preference is studied by con tionships between variables, and to structing a model of a population of a evaluate the kinds of empirical data given size, with specified vital rates and that would be needed to test or falsify probabilities of choice within a range of the hypotheses involved. social categories. Computer simulation was used by For example, in exploring Ayoub's Kunstadter et al. (1963) for analysis of (1959) view that patrilateral parallel the effect of demographic constraints cousin marriage was an "epiphenom on an ideal pattern of marriage: pref enon of a general tendency toward erential matrilateral cross-cousin mar kin-group endogamy," Gilbert and riage. In construction of the demo Hammel (1966:72) took advantage of graphic model, the factors allowed to the experimental potential of the com~ vary were population size and marriage puter by simulating a territorially sub probability by age (which in turn affect divided population with specific mar ed average age at marriage and at riage rules (e.g., incest prohibition, ter ritorial preference for mates), residence rules (patri-virilocal), and demographic that5 TEhgeo mwatihlle mmataicrrayl eqFuBaDti onis :f orP rth(FeB pDro) ba=bi l(iPtyr factors (average reproductive age, age (ENDOG) X Pr(FBDIENDOG)) + (Pr(EXOG) X matching in . marriage, etc.). They Pr(FBDIEXOG)). [n ordinary language, the probabil· hypothesized that the resultant pattern ity that a man will marry his father's brother's of patriJateral parallel cousin marriage daughter is equal to the sum of the probability of his choosing her from among the marriageable girls could be accounted for "as an epiphe within the village (the probability of endogamy nomenon of territorial endogamy times the probability of his marrying his father's alone, without necessarily specifying brother's daughter if he marries within the village) kinship-phrased preferen ce." plus the probability of his choosing her from among After logical clarification of the kin the marriageable girls outside the village (the proba· bility of exogamy times the probability of his mar· ship preference problem was obtained rying his fa ther's brother's daughter if he marries through simulation, Gilbert and Ham- outside the village) (Gilbert and Hammel 1966:80). 378 DOUGLAS R. WHITE chlldbirth, average number of children, generating process is known as Monte and the growth and size of the popula Carlo simulation. In simulating small tion). The results showed the impossibil populations, this process introduces a ity of prescriptive marriage of this type realistic fluctuation in population size in relatively small populations. The over time, and successive runs of the maximum frequency of the marriage program can be used to establish gener type in populations of about a hundred al trends as well as the probabilities of persons is generally between 15 and 24 a society's being reduced to extinction. percent for the simulation model, and By the use of this baseline rnodel, generally between 31 and 45 percent overlay modifications in tenns of differ for initial popUlations of two to three ent marriage rules can be introduced hundred which are ex panding. The au into the program to determine their thors note that in societies with larger effect upon population growth or de popUlations and with a nlatrilateral cline. By this method, Morgan (1970) cross-cousin marriage preference, it is found that for a model where popUla often a pro bleJn to explain why the tion tends to slight natural increase actual frequency of this marriage type without specified marriage rules (ran is lower than might be expected from d01TI mating), the introduction of incest their model. prohibitions (without consideration of Baseline models and overlay models deleterious in breed ing effects) tended are effectively utilized to study in ter slightly to auglnent population growth, acting effects in complex systems while the effects of clan endogamy (Coleman 1964:519-22). The two tended to lead to dying out of a popu examples of simulation of marriage lation in about four hundred years, choice illustrate a means by which com because of restrictions in the availabil plex phenomena can be broken down ity of mates.6 into simpler subsystems by the use of The use of a stochastic process in baseline (i.e., given demographic condi Monte Carlo simulation to estimate the tions) and overlay (i.e., tnarriage prefer chances that a society (or household ence) models. More sophjsticated base type or age grade) will die out under line models can be constructed in certain conditions is one of the impor which variance jn the baseline D10del is tant contributions of stochastic models siInulatecl to help understand the effect (Coleman 1964:527-28). Gilbert and upon the overlay phenomenon (e.g., Hammel (1966:87), in their model, marriage ru les). noted that Monte Carlo sin1ulation "a 1- Morgan (1969) uses a model of dem lows one to speak of the dispersion of ographic constraints, including differ the results." The suitability of sto ent marriage rules (Morgan 1970), to chastic models for analysis of "survival study the survival possi bilities of small, chances" of the components of social closed populations. He uses a demo graphic baseline model where the vital 6 The conditions for the baseline population rules (e.g., birth, death) are set by a mode} were found to be stable in the earlier simUla stochastic process. A computer simula tions (Morgan 1969), and correspond to low-fertil· ity, low-mortality demographic rates. Thus the re tion utilizes the sto chastic pro cess in sults of this simulation are not necessarily general such a way that the population under izable to other conditions. High-fertility, high-mor goes successive demographic transitions tality rates in smalJ popUlations were found to governed by random fluctuation in the exhibit such a degree of random fluctuation that they tended to become extjnct in the absence of any vital rates as detennined by the transi marriage rules after an average span of about four tion probabilities. The use of a random hundred years.

Description:
CHAPTER 9 Mathemati.cal Anthropology. DOUGLAS R. WHITE. INTRODUCTION. This review will introduce the gener- al reader in anthropology to some of.
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.