∗ Cascading Failures in Production Networks † DavidRezzaBaqaee August24,2015 Abstract I show how the extensive margin of firm entry and exit can greatly amplify idiosyncratic shocksinaneconomywithaproductionnetwork. Ishowthatinput-outputmodelswithentry andexitbehaveverydifferentlytomodelswithoutthismargin. Inparticular,insuchmodels, salesprovideaverypoormeasureofthesystemicimportanceoffirmsorindustries. Iderivea newnotionofsystemicinfluencecalledexitcentralitythatcaptureshowexitsinoneindustry will affect equilibrium output. I show that exit centrality need not be monotonically related to an industry’s sales, size, or prices. Unlike the relevant notions of centrality in standard input-outputmodels,exitcentralitydependsontheindustry’sroleasbothasupplierandasa consumerofinputs. Furthermore,Ishowthatgranularitiesinsystemicallyimportantindustries cancauseonefailuretosnowballintoalarge-scaleavalancheoffailures. Inthissense,shocks canbeamplifiedastheytravelthroughthenetwork,whereasinstandardinput-outputmodels theycannot. Keywords: Propagation,networks,macroeconomics,entryandexit ∗FirstVersion: September2013. IthankEmmanuelFarhi, MarcMelitz, AlpSimsek, andJohnCampbellfortheir guidance. IthankDaronAcemoglu,PolAntras,NatalieBau,AubreyClark,BenGolub,GitaGopinath,AlirezaTahbaz- Salehi,ThomasSteinke,OrenZiv,andDavidYang,aswellasmanyseminarparticipants,forhelpfulcomments. Ithank LudvigSinanderforhisdetailedcommentsonanearlierdraft. †LondonSchoolofEconomicsandPoliticalScience,[email protected]. 1 1 Introduction Inthispaper,Iinvestigatehowtheentryandexitoffirmscanacttoamplifyandpropagateshocks in production networks. I model cascades of failures among firms linked through a production network,andshowwhichfirmsandindustriesaresystemicallyimportantforaggregateoutcomes. Ishowthattheextensivemarginofentryisapowerfulpropagationmechanismofshocksthrough productionnetworks. ff Theideathatkeyconsumersorkeysupplierscanhaveoutsizede ectsonaneconomyifthey enter or exit has long been popular with policy makers and the public. Policies as diverse as agricultural subsidies, industrial policy, and government bail-outs frequently have been justified on the grounds of systemic importance. In academic economics, such ideas have been around since at least the time of Hirschman (1958) and Rosenstein-Rodan (1943). However, despite their popularitywithpolicymakers,theseideashavenotbeenasinfluentialinmacroeconomics. Results like those of Hulten (1978) suggest that the systemic importance of firms and industries can be approximatedbytheirsales,eveninthepresenceoflinkagesbetweenfirms,andthereforeappeals tosystemicimportanceareatbestmisguidedandatworstdishonest. However, in recent times, and motivated by current events, these ideas have experienced a resurgence in macroeconomics. After the failure of Lehman Brothers in the United States, the existence of systemically important financial institutions, or SIFIs, became well-accepted in the financeandmacro-financeliteratures. Furthermore,recentworkhasalsohighlightedthatsystemicimportanceneednotbelimitedto financialrelationships. AmemorableexampleofthisiscaseoftheUSautomobilemanufacturing industry, as discussed by Acemoglu et al. (2012). In the fall of 2008, the president of Ford Motor Co., Alan Mulally, requested government support for General Motors and Chrysler, but not for Ford. ThereasonMullalywantedgovernmentsupportforhiscompany’srivalswasthatthefailure ofGMandChryslerwerepredictedtoresultinthefailureofmanyoftheirsuppliers. SinceFord ff relied on many of those same suppliers, Mulally feared that the knock-on e ect on its suppliers could put Ford itself out of business. Mulally’s actions go against the standard expectation that Fordwouldbenefitfromthefailureofitsfiercestrivals,andthesalesofGMdidnottellusthefull storyaboutthepotentialconsequencesofGM’sfailure. While a government bailout of GM and Chrysler prevented a tide of failures in the United States,1 a scenario similar to the one Mulally described did play out in Australia. In May 2013, Ford Australia announced it they would stop manufacturing cars in 2017. Seven months later, GMAustraliaannounceditwouldalsostopmanufacturingcarsin2017. Threemonthsafterthat, in February 2014, Toyota Australia also announced that it would close its manufacturing plants ff at the same time. This e ectively ended automobile manufacturing in Australia. The Australian government predicted that this would result in the loss of over 30,000 jobs, a figure they arrived 1SeeGoolsbeeandKrueger(2015). 2 atbyaddingthenumberofpeopledirectlyemployedbythethreeautomakersandtheAustralian carpartsindustry. EmpiricalworkbyCarvalhoetal.(2014)providesfurthersupportfortheideathatfirmentry andexithaveimportantspill-oversonotherfirmsthroughsupplyanddemandchains. Carvalho etal.(2014)instrumentforfirmexitsusingthe2011Tohokuearthquake,andthenshowthatfirm ff exits have important negative spill-over e ects on both upstream and downstream firms, even whenthesefirmsarenotdirectlyconnectedtotheexitingfirm. Theyshowthatexitsupstreamor downstreamfromafirmreducethefirm’sprofitsandmakethefirmmorelikelytoexit. ff Despitetheimportanceofthesespill-overe ects,standardmacroeconomicmodels,evenones with production networks, do not allow for such forces. In this paper, I explicitly incorporate the extensive margin of firm entry into an input-output model of production, and show that the extensivemarginaltersthequantitativeandqualitativepropertiesofthemodel. This paper contributes to the growing literature on the microeconomic origins of aggregate fluctuations. Two recent strands of this literature are the granular origins hypothesis of Gabaix (2011)andthenetworkoriginshypothesisofAcemogluetal.(2012). Theformerpositsthatshocks ff to large, or granular, firms can have non-trivial e ects on real GDP. The latter posits that shocks ff to highly-connected firms can have non-trivial e ects on real GDP. In practice, both theories emphasizeafirmorindustry’ssize,asmeasuredbyitsshareofsales,asbeingtherelevantmeasure of that player’s importance. The intuition here is that if a firm is systemically important, then in equilibrium, it will have a large fraction of total sales. However, as discussed above, we might expectinterconnectednesstomatterinwaysthatarenotcapturedbypricesortotalquantities. In thispaper,Ishowthatallowingforentryandexitmeansthatthenetworkstructureofproduction can amplify shocks and determine systemic importance in ways that are not captured by size. Furthermore, by combining granularity, networks, and the extensive margin, we can produce dramaticdominochainreactionsthatwouldnotbepresentintheabsenceofanyoneofthesethree ingredients. Toplacemyanalysisinthebroaderliterature,Ifirstshowthatstandardinput-outputmacroe- conomic models that follow Long and Plosser (1983), like Acemoglu et al. (2012), Atalay (2013), orBaqaee(2015)havethreecruciallimitations. First, Ishowthatthesemodelshavetheproperty that their responses to idiosyncratic productivity shocks can be summarized in terms of exoge- ffi ffi nous su cient statistics. Once we compute the relevant su cient statistics, we can discard the ff network structure. So, for example, I show that there are disconnected economies, with di erent householdstastes,thatbehavepreciselylikethenetworkmodels. Thisresultissimilarinspiritto theirrelevanceresultofDupor(1999). ffi Second,Ishowthattherelevantsu cientstatisticsarecloselyrelatedtotheequilibriumsizeof firms. Thismeansthat,withouttheextensivemargin,itisnottheinterconnectionsperse,buthow ff thoseinterconnectionsa ectafirm’ssizethatdeterminesafirm’ssystemicimportance. Ifwecan 3 ffi ff arrive at the same su cient statistics using a di erent (perhaps degenerate) network-structure, the equilibrium responses will be the same. This fact explains why the theoretical implications of the granular hypothesis of Gabaix (2011), where business cycles are driven by large firms, are observationallyequivalenttothetheoreticalimplicationsofthenetworkhypothesisofAcemoglu etal.(2012),wherebusinesscyclesaredrivenbywell-connectedfirms. Third, I show that in canonical input-output models, systemic importance depends only on a firm’sroleasasupplier. Inotherwords,aslongasfirmsiand jhavethesamestrengthconnections to the same customers, then their systemic influence will be the same, regardless of what i and j’s own supply chains look like. This contrasts with our starting anecdote about the American automobileindustrybecauseitwasnotGM’sroleasasupplierofcars,butitsroleasaconsumerof carparts, thatmadeGMsystemicallyimportant. Canonicalinput-outputmodelscannotbeused tounderstandepisodeswhereaproductivityshocktravelsfromconsumersupstreamtosuppliers andthentravelsbackdownstreamtootherconsumers. ffi Whenweallowforentryandexit,allthreeoftheselimitationsdisappear. First,thesu cient- statisticapproachbreaksdown. Thisisbecausetheextensivemarginmakes“systemicimportance” anendogenouslydeterminedvaluethatisnotwell-approximatedbyequilibriumsizeorprices. A firmthatmayseemlikeasmallplayer,whenmeasuredbysales,canhavepotentiallylargeimpacts on aggregate outcomes. On the other hand, a firm that may seem like a key player, as measured ff by sales, can have relatively minor e ects on the equilibrium. Furthermore, the endogenously- determined measures of systemic influence depend on a firm’s role as both a supplier and as a consumer, as well as on how many close substitutes there are for the firm. The fact that systemicimportanceisunrelatedtosalescontrastssharplywiththeneoclassicalworldofHulten’s theorem. Hulten (1978) shows that with arbitrary constant-returns production functions and ff arbitrarynetworkstructures,thee ectonoutputofamarginalTFPshocktoanindustrydepends onlyonthatindustry’ssales. Thisresultisnolongertruewhenwehaveameaningfulentry-exit margin. ThemodelpresentedinthispaperalsoallowsustocombinethegranularhypothesisofGabaix (2011) and the network hypothesis of Acemoglu et al. (2012) in a new and interesting way. In particular, when firms are not infinitesimal, extensive margin shocks can be locally amplified via ff interconnections. In other words, when a large and well-connected firm exits, it can set o an avalancheoffirmfailuresthatactuallygetslargerasitgatherssteam. Thistypeofamplificationis impossibleincanonicalmodels,whereshockscanonlydecayastheytravelthroughthenetwork. ff Thispaperalsocontributestothewiderliteratureondi usioninnetworktheory,bybridging the gap between two alternative modelling traditions. Loosely speaking, there are two popular ff approaches to modelling di usion on social networks. First, there are continuous models of ff di usion like Katz (1953). Here, nodes influence each other in continuous ways – shocks travel awayfromtheirsourcelikewavesandslowlydieout. Thestrengthoftheconnectionsbetweenthe 4 nodescontrolstherateofdecay. Suchshocks,sometimescalledpulseprocesses,arecharacterized bygeometricsums. Itiswell-knownthatsuchmodelsareincapableoflocalamplification: ashock ff to one node will always have its largest e ect at its source, and the shock will decay as it travels throughtheconnections.2 ThesestructureswerefirststudiedbyLeontief(1936)inhisinput-output modeloftheeconomy. Theothertraditionconsistsofmodelsthatbehavediscontinuously,astypifiedbyMorris(2000) orElliottetal.(2012). Inthisclassofmodels,sometimescalledthresholdmodels,eachnodehasa thresholdandiseitheractiveorinactive. Whenanodecrossesitsthresholditchangesstatesand, by changing states, pushes its neighbors closer to their thresholds. Such models are frequently used to study the spread of epidemics, products, or even ideas. One of the earliest and most influential threshold models is the Schelling (1971) model of segregation. Threshold models do not have wave-like properties since the rate at which shocks decay is not geometric. Crucially, these models are capable of generating local amplification – that is, shocks can be amplified as ffi theytravelthroughthenetwork. Unfortunately,thesemodelsarenotoriouslydi culttoanalyze. In this paper, I consider a model that bridges the gap between the continuous and discrete models. Specifically,Iexplicitlyaccountforthemassoffirmsinagivenindustry. Industrieswith a continuum of firms behave continuously – the mass of firms responds continuously to shocks. Ontheotherhand,lumpyindustries,withonlyafewfirms,behavediscontinuously. Forinstance, anegativeshocktoanunconcentratedindustry,saybakeries,willresultinsomefractionofbakers ff exiting. The fraction exiting will be a continuous function of the size of the shock. The e ect on a neighboring upstream industry, like flour mills, or downstream industry, like cafes, will be attenuated by the strength of its connections to bakeries. However, a negative shock to a highly ff concentratedindustry,likeautomobilemanufacturing,willhavenoe ectonthenumberoffirms unless it is large enough to force an exit. But once a large firm exits, it imparts an additional impulsetothesizeoftheshock,whichcantriggeracascade. Becausethemodelisflexibleenough to express both behaviors, I can provide conditions under which we would expect a continuous approximationtoadiscontinuousmodeltoperformwell. The idea of cascading – domino-like – chain reactions also appears outside of economics. In ff particular,modelsofcontagionanddi usionlikethethresholdmodelsconsideredbyKempeetal. (2003) have these features. In these models, notions of connectedness play a key role since the only way contagion can spread is via connections between nodes. An interesting implication of embeddingacontagionmodelintoageneralequilibriumeconomyistherolepricesandaggregate demand play – a role that does not have analogues in other threshold models. Typically, in a threshold model, shocks can only travel along edges. Contagion can only spread to nodes who are connected to an infected node. This important intuition breaks down in general equilibrium models since all firms are linked together via aggregate supply and demand. This means that 2See,forexample,page253inBermanandPlemmons(1979)andalsoappendixD. 5 general equilibrium forces can act like long-distance carriers of disease. Shocks in one fragile ff industry, like the financial industry, can jump via aggregate demand or supply, to a di erent fragileindustrylikeautomobilemanufacturing,evenifthesetwoindustriesarenotconnected. This paper is belongs to the literature seeking to derive aggregate fluctuations by combining microeconomic shocks with local interactions. Empirical work on this front includes Foerster et al. (2011), Di Giovanni et al. (2014), Barrot and Sauvagnat (2015), Carvalho et al. (2014), and Acemoglu et al. (2015). Theoretical work can be roughly divided into two categories. The first categoryarepapersthatbuildonthemulti-sectorneoclassicalmodelofLongandPlosser(1983), like Horvath (2000), Acemoglu et al. (2012), Atalay (2013), and Jones (2011). These are log-linear models of propagation, and follow the tradition of Leontief (1936) in having linear-geometric ff di usion. As shown by Hulten (1978), the propagation of TFP shocks in such models is, at least locally, tied to the distribution of firm sizes. This means that in order for a firm to be systemically important, it must have high sales. The second category are models that do not satisfytherequirementsofHulten’stheorem. Thesemodels,likeJovanovic(1987),Durlauf(1993), andScheinkmanandWoodford(1994),featurestrongnonlinearities,theirsalesdistributionisnot ffi ff a decisive su cient statistic, and they do not feature the kind of geometric patterns of di usion found in input-output models. However, these models depart dramatically from the standard ffi assumptions of macroeconomics and can be di cult to work with. This paper has elements in commonwithbothoftheseliteratures. Theindividualingredientsinmymodelareveryfamiliarto macroeconomists–monopolisticcompetition,free-entry,andinput-outputlinkagesviaconstant- elasticitity-of-substitution production functions. However, the presence of all three ingredients togetherresultsinstronglynonlinearinteractionsandanuncouplingofsystemicimportancefrom thedistributionofsales. Thestructureofpaperisasfollows. Insection2,Isetupthemodelanddefineitsequilibrium. In section 3, I characterize the equilibrium conditional on the mass of entrants in each industry and define some key centrality measures. In section 4, I study how the model behaves when the extensive margin of firm entry and exit is shut down. I prove results showing that the network ffi structure can be summarized by su cient statistics related to size. I also show that we can think ff of these models as non-interconnected models with di erent parameters. In section 5, I allow for firm entry and exit. First, I characterize the model’s responses to shocks in the limit where ffi all firms are massless. I show that su cient statistics are no longer available, and I derive an endogenous measure of influence called exit centrality. Then, I consider the case when firms can have positive mass, and show that with atomistic firms, shocks can be locally amplified. I prove an approximability result showing conditions under which we can approximate an intractable discontinuous model using a tractable continuous model. Motivated by Ford’s request for a ffi bailout of GM, I also consider whether e cient bail-outs can be identified by surveying firms. Specifically,whencanwetrustonefirm’stestimonyaboutwhetherornotanotherfirmshouldbe 6 bailedout. Iconcludeinsection6. 2 Model In this section, I spell out the structure of the model and define the equilibrium. There are three types of agents: households, firms, and a government. Each firm belongs to an industry, and thereareNindustries. Therearetwoperiods: entrydecisionshappensimultaneouslyinperiod1, productionandconsumptiontakeplaceinperiod2. Household’sProblem The households in the model are homogenous with a unit mass. The representative household maximizesutility σ U(c1,...,cN) = (cid:88)N βkσ1ckσ−σ1σ−1 , k=1 wherec representscompositeconsumptionofvarietiesfromindustrykandσ > 0istheelasticity k β ≥ of substitution across industries. The weights 0 determine household tastes for goods and k services from the different industries. The composite consumption good produced by industry k isgivenby ε k ck = M−kϕk(cid:88)Nk ∆kc(k,i)εkε−k1εk−1 , i=1 where c(k,i) is household consumption from firm i in industry k and ε > 1 is the elasticity of k substitution across firms within industry k. Here, N is the number of firms active in industry k k and ∆ is the exogenous weight of each firm.3 The total mass of varieties in industry k is given k −ϕ by M = N ∆ . Finally, the term M k controls the strength of the love-of-variety effect. If we let k k k k ϕ = /ε ϕ = 1 , then there is no love-of-varieties, and if we let 0, we get the standard Dixit and k k k Stiglitz(1977)demandsystem.4 Thehousehold’sbudgetisgivenby (cid:88) (cid:88) p(k,i)c(k,i)∆ = wl+ π(k,i)∆ −τ, k k k,i k,i wherep(k,i)isthepriceoffirmiinindustrykandπ(k,i)isfirmiinindustryk’sprofits. Thewage iswandlaborisinelasticallysuppliedatl. Fortherestofthepaper,andwithoutlossofgenerality, 3Ifwetakethelimit∆ →0,thissumconvergestoaRiemannintegral. k 4See section 5.1 for more discussion about the significance of the love-of-varieties effect in this model. Love of varietiescanbethoughtofasareducedformforamorecomplexmodelwhereincreasingproductvarietyimproves thematchbetweenproductsandconsumers. Andersonetal.(1992)provideamicrofoundationforthisviaadiscrete choicemodelwhereeachconsumerconsumesonlyasinglevariety,butthereexistsaCESrepresentativeconsumerfor thepopulationofconsumers. 7 wetakelabortobethenumerairesothatw = 1,andfixthesupplyoflaborl = 1. Lumpsumtaxes τ bythegovernmentaredenoted . Firms’Problem Letfirmiinindustrykhaveprofits (cid:88)N (cid:88)Nl π(k,i) = p(k,i)y(k,i)− p(l,j)x(k,i,l,j)∆ −wh(k,i)−wf +τ , l k k l=1 j where p(k,i) is the price and y(k,i) is the output of the firm. Inputs from firm j in industry l are x(k,i,l,j)andlaborinputsareh(k,i). Finally,inordertooperate,eachfirmmustpayafixedcost f k τ in units of labor and the firm potentially receives a lump sum subsidy . The firm’s production k function(oncethefixedcosthasbeenpaid)isconstant-returns-to-scale σ y(k,i) = αkσ1(zkl(k,i))σ−σ1 +(cid:88)N ωkσ1,lx(k,i,l)σ−σ1σ−1 . l=1 σ > ω Here, 0isagaintheelasticityofsubstitutionamonginputs,and istheshareparameterfor kl howintensivelyfirmsinindustrykusecompositeinputsfromindustryl. TheN×Nmatrixofω , kl Ω denotedby ,determinesthenetwork-structureofthiseconomy. Onecanthinkofthismatrixas α > theadjacencymatrixofaweighteddirectedgraph. Theparameter 0givestheintensitywith k whichfirmsinindustrykuselabor(netoffixedcosts). Laborproductivityshocks,liketheonesconsideredbyAcemogluetal.(2012)andAtalay(2013) are denoted by z . Note that when σ (cid:44) 1, a productivity shock z to industry k is equivalent to k k changing that industry’s labor intensity from α to α zσ−1. Therefore, as long as σ (cid:44) 1, we can k k k α think of as including both the productivity shock and the labor intensity. This way we do not k need to directly make reference to the shocks z since they are just equivalent to changing α. This equivalence breaks down when σ = 1, and in those cases, we shall have to work directly with z. Forthemajorityofthispaper, Ifocusonthepropagationoftheseproductivityshocks. Thesame methodscaneasilybeusedtostudyothershockslikefixed-costshocksordemandshocks. Thecompositeintermediateinputfromindustrylusedbyfirmiinindustrykis εl x(k,i,l) = Ml−ϕl(cid:88)Nl ∆lx(k,i,l,j)εlε−l1εl−1 , j=1 whereε istheelasticityofsubstitutionacrossdifferentfirmswithinindustryl. Asbefore,theterm l −ϕ M l affects the strength of the love-of-varieties effect in industry l. Letting ϕ = 0 gives us the l l traditionalDixit-Stiglitzformulation. Notethattheelasticitiesofsubstitutionarethesameforall 8 usersofanindustry’soutput. Government’sProblem Thegovernmentrunsabalancedbudgetsothat (cid:88) τ M = τ. k k k For now, we assume that the government is completely passive. In section 5.5, we return to how ff thegovernmentcanvaryitstaxesandsubsidiestoa ecttheequilibrium. Notation Lete denotetheithstandardbasisvector. LetΩbetheN×Nmatrixwhoseijthelementisequalto i ω . LetαandβbetheN×1vectorsconsistingofαsandβs. LetMbetheN×Ndiagonalmatrix ij i i whose ith element is M, and let M˜ be the N ×N diagonal matrix whose ith diagonal element is i 1−ϕiεi equaltoM εi−1 . Let◦denotetheelement-wiseorHadamardproduct,anddiag : RN → RN2 bethe i operatorthatmapsavectortoadiagonalmatrix. Tosimplifythenotation,whenavariableappears withoutasubscript,thisrepresentsthematrixofallsuchvariables,andtheobjectvs,wherevisa vectorandsisascalar,shouldbeinterpretedasthevectorvraisedtothepowerofselementwise. Definition 2.1. An economy E is defined by the tuple E = (β,Ω,α,ε,σ, f,∆,ϕ). The vector β Ω α contains household taste parameters, captures the input-output share parameters, contains ε > the industrial labor share parameters, 1 is the vector of industrial elasticities of substitution, σ > 0isthecross-industryelasticityofsubstitution, f isthevectoroffixedcosts,∆isthevectorof ϕ ff massesoffirmsineachindustry,and istheparametercontrollingthelove-of-varietye ect. Equilibrium WestudythesubgameperfectNashequilibrium. Inperiod1,potentialentrantsmakesimultaneous entry decisions. In period 2, firms play general equilibrium conditional on period 1’s entry decisions. Define a markup function µ : RN ×RN → RN to be a function that maps number of entrants{N } andproductivityshocksz tomarkupsforeachindustry. Nowwecandefinegeneral k k k equilibrium as follows. I assume that firms set their prices to equal the markup function times theirmarginalcost. Definition 2.2. A general equilibrium of economy E is a collection of prices p(i,k), wage w, and input demands x(i,k,l,j), outputs y(i,k), consumptions c(i,k) and labor demands l(i,k) such that fornumberofentrants{N }N ,vectorofproductivityshocksz,andmarkupfunctionµ(N,z): k k=1 9 (i) Eachfirmminimizesitscostssubjecttodemandforitsgoodsgiventhemarkupfunction, (ii) therepresentativehouseholdchoosesconsumptiontomaximizeutility, (iii) thegovernmentrunsabalancedbudget, (iv) marketsforeachgoodandlaborclear. Notethatpricesandquantitiesinageneralequilibriumdependonthenumberofentrants{N }, k µ thevectorofproductivityshocks,andtheassumedindustry-levelmarkups . Conditions(ii)–(iv) are standard, but condition (i) merits further discussion. Condition (i) is deliberately vague. It simply requires that the firms minimize their costs, given the demand they face and leaves their µ choice over prices unspecified – it simply requires that there be some function that determines theirmarkupsasafunctionofthenumberofentrants{N }andtheproductivitiesz. k µ The exact nature of the markup function , which will depend on what we assume about competition in each industry, will play an important role in our analysis. However, for now, we µ canleavethemarketstructuregeneral. Notethatbychoosing correctly,wecanrepresentmany ff di erentpopularmodelsofcompetitionincludingCournot,Dixit-Stiglitz,andperfectcompetition. Let Π : RN+ × RN+ → RN be the function mapping the masses of entrants M and vector of productivity shocks z to industrial profits assuming general equilibrium in period 2. In theorem 3.5,Ianalyticallycharacterizethisfunction. Definition2.3. Avectorofintegers{N }N isanequilibriumnumberofentrantsif k k=1 Πi(Mi,M−i,z) ≥ 0 > Πi(Mi+∆i,M−i,z) (i ∈ {1,2,...,N}), whereM = N ∆ ,forall j. j j j Intuitively, a vector of integers is an equilibrium number of entrants if all firms make non- negativeprofits,andtheentryofanadditionalfirminanyindustryresultsinfirmsinthatindustry ∆ → making negative profits. Note that if we let 0, the entry inequalities become a zero-profit i equalitycondition. Beforeanalyzingthemodel,ithelpstodefinesomekeystatistics. Thesearestandarddefinitions fromtheliteratureonmonopolisticcompetition. See,forexample,BettendorfandHeijdra(2003). Definition2.4. Thepriceindexforindustrykisgivenby 1 pk = M−kϕkεk(cid:88)Nk ∆kp(k,i)1−εk1−εk , i 10
Description: