ebook img

Capitalism without Capital: Accounting for the crash PDF

187 Pages·2015·2.357 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Capitalism without Capital: Accounting for the crash

Capitalism without Capital This page intentionally left blank Capitalism without Capital Accounting for the crash Alan Shipman Lecturer in Economics, Open University, UK © Alan Shipman 2015 All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of this publication may be made without written permission. No portion of this publication may be reproduced, copied or transmitted save with written permission or in accordance with the provisions of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under the terms of any licence permitting limited copying issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency, Saffron House, 6-10 Kirby Street, London EC1N 8TS. Any person who does any unauthorized act in relation to this publication may be liable to criminal prosecution and civil claims for damages. The author has asserted his right to be identified as the author of this work in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. First published 2015 by PALGRAVE MACMILLAN Palgrave Macmillan in the UK is an imprint of Macmillan Publishers Limited, registered in England, company number 785998, of Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS. Palgrave Macmillan in the US is a division of St Martin’s Press LLC, 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, NY 10010. Palgrave Macmillan is the global academic imprint of the above companies and has companies and representatives throughout the world. Palgrave® and Macmillan® are registered trademarks in the United States, the United Kingdom, Europe and other countries. E-ISBN: 978–1–137–44244–4 This book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully managed and sustained forest sources. Logging, pulping and manufacturing processes are expected to conform to the environmental regulations of the country of origin. A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Shipman, Alan, 1966– Capitalism without capital : accounting for the crash / Alan Shipman. pages cm Summary: “An unusual consensus has developed among economists that the ‘long boom’ before 2008, and the subsequent crisis and recession, resulted from a global excess of capital. Over-supply of saving drive down capital costs, encouraging excessively risky investment and preventing the scrapping of outmoded plant. Capital’s inexorable growth is also blamed for a prolonged squeeze on wages, rising elite wealth and worsening global inequality. This book explores the obvious clash between such arguments and actual measurements of capital, which show a small and shrinking ‘productive’ component, and a deepening disconnection between capital accumulation and economic growth. It traces the conflict to the continued absence of consistent definitions or measurements of capital, and neglect of the complex connection between aggregate capital and wealth. Capital ‘gains’ and ‘losses’, and the growing domination of income statements by balance sheets, undermine attempts to sidestep the problem by reconstituting economics as a system of flows”—Provided by publisher. ISBN 978–1–137–44243–7 (hardback) 1. Capitalism. 2. Financial crises. 3. Recessions. I. Title. HB501.S5854 2015 330.12’2—dc23 2015003629 Contents List of Tables vi Introduction 1 1 An Obvious Excess of Capital 9 2 A Still More Obvious Excess: Capital as Wealth 27 3 In Practice It’s Scarce 51 4 What Isn’t There? Capital Definitions and Measurements 71 5 The Destination of Wealth 93 6 Economics without Capital 123 7 Economies without Capital 139 References 169 Index 177 List of Tables 5.1 Composition of gross capital stock, Euro Area 17, % 107 5.2 Net stock of fixed assets (at current prices), US 108 5.3 Composition of private net wealth, various countries, 1990–2010 (percentages) 109 7.1 Asset holdings: median household, 2013 (EUR thousands) 142 7.2 General government gross debt, G7 countries, 1996–2013 (% of GDP) 163 vi Introduction Off the shelf Early versions of ideas distilled here took shape in the Marshall Library of Economics. The ‘Marshall’ has, for over 40 years, been housed in the architecturally dubious but intellectually salubrious Austin Robinson Building, with offshooting corridors that run past rooms named after John Maynard Keynes and James Meade. Over the years, the Marshall’s book and journal stock has been constantly replaced and updated, so that few of the tomes that informed Economics Triposes of the past now remain on display. Vast amounts of new writing (and some new thinking) have occurred in economics since the library’s inauguration, and the edited highlights have trickled remorselessly onto its shelves. Yet while the contents continually change, they have never expanded. The stacks remain far enough apart for natural light to bathe the reading desks, and retain enough empty space to per- suade next year’s intake that there is still something more to be said. Although not all can match the Marshall’s scenic windows and squeaky floors, other libraries have taken the same one-in, one-out approach to managing stock. I can confirm this from the documen- tary research that went into this book. Almost all the referenced titles that had been published before 2000 were no longer stocked in librar- ies, and were eventually obtained as second-hand copies that had been withdrawn and sold by those same libraries (the rubber rejec- tion stamps ranging from Manchester to Michigan). Libraries’ lack of expansion is, of course, an intellectual if not an optical illusion. The Marshall (and its many surrounding libraries) 1 2 Capitalism without Capital holds an expanding array of items that are not on display, but stored in basements or off-sit archives, to be called back if eager readers with long memories wish to revisit them. Only the miniaturizing wizardry of microfilms, databases and disks have stopped these subterranean storage vaults fanning out into collision with the metro tunnels and mining shafts. Digitization arrived just in time to avert a knowledge- driven deforestation. Now libraries can expand invisibly, as portals to an electronic collection that can grow without limit, until Iceland sinks beneath the weight of its snow-cooled server farms. The stock of claims to economic knowledge is therefore not as bounded as the Marshall’s perennially uncluttered aisles might sug- gest. Academic and professional economists have been far from unproductive over the past half century, even though they have ren- dered numerous economies unproductive during that time. Indeed, under ever-rising pressure to publish, they spew out more articles and books than ever, a surge tide from which this slender volume strug- gles to detach itself. But the degree course which most of the Marshall’s term-time visi- tors are pursuing does not expand in scale or extend in length. An undergraduate BA in Economics is still completed in three years of three terms, each no more than eight weeks long. Students complain of a growing intensity of work, but they have always done so. The time traditionally set aside for local rowing, brewing, playmaking and late- night crenellation climbing has not been noticeably squeezed. Those who deliver the courses insist that they have relentlessly updated them to include the latest theoretical and empirical advances. So if the standard commodities, wage-profit frontiers, multiplier effects and capital reversals of a generation ago are expunged from today’s curriculum, it can only be because they have been encompassed or superseded. Either they are needed no more, or the historians next door can pick them up. According to its custodians, then, the stock of relevant economic knowledge has not grown. It has merely been transformed within unchanging boundaries of time and space. New breakthroughs shrink past general theories into special cases of one more encompassing, or show them to be wholly dispensable, like bygone chemistries’ aether and phlogiston. Mathematics and experimentation, the two levers with which economists seek to shift their ground from social to natural science, have been especially effective (in the view of their Introduction 3 practitioners) – to raising quality while even reducing quantity. The laboratory tests (on computer-simulated economies, and occasion- ally unsuspecting residents of a real one) reject substantially more past assertions than they accept. The algebraic ‘formalizations’ rid the subject of excess verbiage, ultimately reducing it to a sequence of theorems that a passing linear programmer could master in an afternoon. While heterodox economists protest that much of value has been ditched to make space for the newly equation-filled orthodoxy, they reinforce the impression of zero-sum knowledge gain by designing courses that teach the mainstream and some alternatives and still compressing them into the standard one- or three-year courses. Concerned as they are to reinstil a critical realism into the subject, a temporal realism rules out any expansion of received wisdom that would detain the learners longer. Lengthening the instruction period is impossible when students’ debts rise in direct proportion to it. Intensifying the injection of new knowledge, to cram more in, would collide with other calls on learners’ time, be it the essential relaxation from study or the evenings behind the counter that are needed to finance it. Undazzled by the ever more sophisticated models and forecasts, the public concluded from the widely unforeseen crash of 2008 that economists knew a lot less than they thought. So few can plausibly dispute the claim that their stock of useful knowledge can evolve and transform without growing. Many would be surprised to be told it has not shrunk, with new ideas subtracting more than they add. The subject’s greatest architects have always engaged in comprehen- sive demolition of what previously stood, before beginning their reconstruction. Despite the vast difference in their aims, this was the strategy adopted in common by (among many others) Marx against the free marketeers, Keynes against the ‘classics’ (including Marx), the General Equilibrium and Rational Expectations theorists against the Keynesians, Barro (1974) and Sargent and Wallace (1975) against any advocacy of fiscal policy effectiveness, Robinson (1954) and Felipe and McCombie (2001) against any models based on aggregate pro- duction functions and Granger and Newbold (1974) against all previ- ous time-series analysis. But if economists want this in relation to their own stock of knowl- edge, they should accept it might apply to other stocks as well.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.