ebook img

Business Economics and Managerial Decision Making PDF

501 Pages·2004·4.941 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Business Economics and Managerial Decision Making

BUSINESS ECONOMICS AND MANAGERIAL DECISION MAKING Trefor Jones Manchester School of Management UMIST 4 PART I g CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND BUSINESS OBJECTIVES INTRODUCTION Firms are major economic institutions in market economies. They come in all shapes andsizes,buthavethefollowingcommoncharacteristics: g Owners. g Managers. g Objectives. g Apoolofresources(labour,physicalcapital,¢nancialcapitalandlearnedskillsand competences)tobeallocatedrolesbymanagers. g Administrativeororganizationalstructuresthroughwhichproductionis organized. g Performanceassessmentbyowners,managersandotherstakeholders. Whateveritssize,a¢rmisownedbysomeoneorsomegroupofindividualsororganiza- tions. These are termed shareholders and they are able to determine the objectives and activities of the ¢rm. They also appoint the senior managers who will make day-to-day decisions. The owners bear the risks associated with operating the ¢rm and have the right to receive the residual income or pro¢ts. Where ownership rights are dispersed, control of the ¢rm may not lie with the shareholders but with senior managers. This divorce between ownership and control and its implication for the operation and performanceofthe¢rmisatthecentreofmanyoftheissuesdealtwithinthisbook. OWNERSHIP STRUCTURES The dominant model of the ¢rm in Western economies is the limited liability company owned by shareholders, but the form varies signi¢cantly between countries. In some countries the control rights of the owners are limited by powers given to stakeholders whomayshareintheappointmentandsupervisionofmanagersandinthedetermina- tion of the enterprise’s objectives. In Germany, for example, large companies recognize the role of workers and other groups by giving them half the positions on the supervisory board that oversees the management board (Douma 1997). There are also ¢rms owned by members and operated as co-operative or mutual enterprises and some ownedbynationalandlocalgovernment. Thenotionthatprivatelyownedenterprisesshouldberunintheinterestsofshare- holders is not a characteristic of companies in all advanced economies. Yoshimori (1995)proposedthatshareholdercompaniescanbeclassi¢edasfollows: g Monistic ^ where the company serves a single interest group, normally share- holders.ThesetypesofcompaniesarecommonlyfoundintheUKandtheUSA. g Dualistic ^ where the company serves two interest groups. Shareholders are the CHAPTER 1 g OWNERSHIP CONTROL AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 5 primary group but employees’ interests are also served. These types of companies arecommonlyfoundinFranceandGermany. g Pluralistic^wherethecompanyservestheinterestsofstakeholdersinthecompany and not just shareholders. Employee and supplier interests may be paramount. SuchcompaniesarefoundinJapan. Since Yoshimori’s study some commentators have argued that there has been some degree of convergence between European and Anglo-American forms of corporate organizations because of greater international competition between enterprises. Likewise, commercial and economic forces in Japan have put signi¢cant pressure on companies to reduce the emphasis on the long-term employment of sta¡ and place greateremphasisonpro¢tability. PATTERNS OF SHAREHOLDING Thepattern of shareownership varies betweencountries andwithtime. In theUK and the USA, ownership is more widely dispersed than in continental Europe and Japan whereitismoreconcentrated. UKshareownership Table1.1presentsdataonshareownershipintheUKfrom1963to2001. Table1.1 ShareholdingintheUK Owners 1963 1975 1989 1994 1997 2001 (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) Individuals 54.0 37.5 20.6 20.3 16.5 14.8 Institutions 30.3 48.0 58.5 60.2 56.3 50.0 Ofwhich: Pensionfunds 6.4 16.8 30.6 27.8 22.1 16.1 Insurancecompanies 10.0 15.9 18.6 21.9 23.6 20.0 Companies 5.1 3.0 3.8 1.1 1.2 1.0 Overseas 7.0 5.6 12.8 16.3 24.0 31.9 Others 3.6 5.9 4.3 3.1 2.0 2.3 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Source Compiledbyauthorusingdatafrom: CSO(1993)Shareregistersurvey1993,EconomicTrends,No480,London,HMSO CSO(1995)ShareOwnership,London,HMSO CSO(1999)Shareownership,EconomicTrends,No543,London,HMSO NationalStatistics(2002)ShareOwnership2001,http://www.statistics.gov.uk 6 PART I g CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND BUSINESS OBJECTIVES Table1.2 StructureofshareownershipinEurope2000 Typeofinvestor France Germany Italy Spain UK (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) Individuals 8 16 25 30 16 Private¢nancialenterprises 29 18 20 14 48 Privatenon-¢nancialorganizations 21 40 25 20 3 Publicsector 6 6 15 0 0 Foreigninvestors 36 20 15 36 32 Unidenti¢ed 1 Total 100 100 100 100 100 Source CompiledbyauthorusingdatafromFESE(2002)ShareOwnershipStructureinEurope2002,Brussels, http://www.fese.be Thekeyfeaturesare: g The largest group of domestic owners of company shares are ¢nancial institutions. g Financial institutions’ share of ownership increased between 1963 and 1997, but fellto50%in2001. g Individual ownership of shares has been in long-term decline and fell to 14.8% in 2001. g Overseas ownership of UK companies has increased and stood at 31.9% in 2001. This trend re£ects the growing internationalisation of the asset portfolios held by ¢nancialinstitutions. ShareholdinginEurope ComparativedatafortheownershipofsharesinFrance,Germany,Italy,Spainandthe UK for the year 2000 are presented in Table 1.2. It shows that in each country the structuresaredi¡erentinbroadtermscomparedwiththeUK: g Holdingsby¢nancialinstitutionsarelower. g Holdingsbynon-¢nancialcompaniesaremoreimportant,particularlyinGermany. g IndividualownershipismoreimportantinItalyandSpain,butlesssoinFrance. g Foreign owners are more important in France and Spain, but less signi¢cant in GermanyandItaly. CLASSIFYING FIRMS AS OWNER OR MANAGEMENT CONTROLLED The pattern of share ownership at company level varies widely. In the UK, quoted companies ownership is generally described as being widely dispersed among large numbers of shareholders. The largest shareholder often owns 5% or less of the stock CHAPTER 1 g OWNERSHIP CONTROL AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 7 and a signi¢cant proportion is owned by non-bank ¢nancial institutions. The board of directors typically own a tiny proportion of the shares, often much less than 0.5%. Thus, managers rather than owners control many medium and large-sized companies and set the ¢rm’s objectives. In France and Germany shareholding tends to be more concentrated with greater blocks of shares held by companies and banks. According to Denis and McConnell (2003) concentrated ownership structures are more likely to be found in most countries in contrast to the dispersed ownership patterns that are typicalonlyoftheUKandtheUSA. How then can companies be classi¢ed as owner or managerially controlled? If a single shareholder holds more than 50% of the stock, assuming one vote per share, then they can outvote the remaining shareholders and control the company. If the largest shareholder owns slightly less than 50% of the equity then they can be outvotediftheothershareholdersformedaunitedfront.Ifthemajorityofshareholders do not form a united front or do not vote, then an active shareholder with a holding of substantiallylessthan50%couldcontrolthecompany. Berle and Means (1932), who ¢rst identi¢ed the divorce between ownership and control, argued that a stake of more than 20% would be su⁄cient for that shareholder to control a company but less than 20% would be insu⁄cient and the company would be management-controlled. Radice (1971) used a largest shareholding of 15% to classify a ¢rm as owner-controlled; and a largest shareholder owning less than 5% to classify a ¢rm as managerially controlled. Nyman and Silberston (1978) severely criticized the ‘‘cut-o¡’’ or threshold method of assessing control and argued that the distribution and ownership of holdings should be examined more closely. They emphasized that there was a need to recognize coalitions of interests, particularly of families,thatdonotemergefromthecrudedata. Cubbin and Leech (1983) also criticized the simple cut-o¡ points for classifying ¢rms. They argued that control was a continuous variable that measures the discretion with which the controlling group is able to pursue its own objectives without being outvoted by other shareholders. Management controllers, they argued, wouldbeexpectedtoexhibitahigherdegreeofcontrolforanygivenlevelofsharehold- ingthanwouldexternalshareholders. They then developed a probabilistic voting model in which the degree of control is de¢ned as the probability of the controlling shareholder(s) securing majority support in a contested vote. Control is de¢ned as an arbitrary 95% chance of winning a vote. This ability depends on the dispersion of shareholdings, the proportion of shareholders voting and the probability of voting shareholders supporting the controlling group. The likelihood of the controlling group winning increases as the proportion voting falls and the more widely held are the shares. Applying their analysis to a sample of 85 companies, they concluded that with a 10% shareholder turnout, in 73 companies less than a 10% holding was necessary for control and in 37 companies with a 5% turnout,lessthana5%holdingwasnecessaryforcontrol. Controlofacompanyisthereforeafunctionofthefollowingfactors: g Thesizeofthelargestholding. g Thesizeanddistributionoftheremainingshares. g Thewillingnessofothershareholderstoformavotingblock. 8 PART I g CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND BUSINESS OBJECTIVES g thewillingnessofothershareholderstobeactiveandtovoteagainstthecontrolling group. Case Study 1.1 Manchester United – owner or managerially controlled? Manchester United epitomizestheconflicts betweencommercialization andthe influence ofsupporters.Theclub’soriginslieintheformationofafootballteambytheworkersofthe Yorkshire and Lancashire Railway Company. It joined the Football League in 1892 in its fourth year of existence. The club finished bottom in their first two seasons and became founder members of the second division. However, since returning to the first division in 1906 and winning the title in 1909, they have played only 10 seasons in a lower division. Until the early 1960s, no shareholder had overall control of the club. In 1958, Louis Edwards, a Manchester businessman was elected to the board at the behest of the then manager Matt Busby. This was at the end of the most successful period in the club’s history having been League champions in 1952, 1956 and 1957. In 1962 he was elected chairmanowningonly17ofthe4,132issuedshares.By1964,hehadacquiredamajority and controlling interest in the club. In 1981 his son Martin became chief executive of the club.In1989,MartintriedtosellhiscompleteinterestintheclubtoMichaelKnightonfor £20m,butthedealfellthrough.In1991theclubwasfloatedonthestockexchange.This led to the most successful period in the club’s playing history. It won the first Premier Leaguetitlein1993,fivemoreinthenextsevenyearsandtheEuropeanCupin1999–the latter a featthey hadpreviouslyachieved in 1968. The changing nature of football and the dangers of flotation were highlighted by the £635m takeover bid made for the club in 1998 by BSkyB. The satellite television station, 40% owned by Rupert Murdoch’s media empire News International, shows live Premiership football on subscription channels. Payments from television companies are a significant source of income for the club. The bid was not motivated by the failure of the club’s management, but by the strategy of BSkyB. It was agreed to by the board of directors, but was vetoed by the government after a reference to the Monopolies and Mergers Commission. The bidder was forced to reduce its stake in the company to below 10%. This left BSkyB owning 9.99% of the share capital and still being the largest shareholder inthe company. Sinceflotation,MartinEdwardshasgraduallyreducedhisstakeintheclubto14%in 1998 and to 0.7% in 2002. The club’s shares are now more widely dispersed with some 20,000smallshareholdersowning3.5%andthedirectorsaround3%.Thelargestholdings in September 2002were: % BSkyB 9.99 Cubic Expression 8.65 Mountbarrow Investment 6.54 LandsdownePartners 3.11 E.M.Watkins 2.31 C.M. Edwards 0.70 Other directors 0.10 In September and early October 2003 there was significant trading, giving the following estimated structure: CHAPTER 1 g OWNERSHIP CONTROL AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 9 % CubicExpression Ltd 23.2 (J.P. McManusandJohn Magnier,Irish businessmen) MalcolmGlazer 8.9 (TampaBayBuccaneers, USAowner) Mountbarrow Investment 6.5 (HarryDobson, Canadian-based Scottish businessman) UBS 5.9 (Financialinstitution) TalpaCapital 4.1 (Johnde Moi,Dutchtelevision tycoon) LandsdownePartners 3.7 (Financialinstitution) Legaland General 3.3 (Financialinstitution) E.M.Watkins 2.3 (United director) Amvesscap 1.8 (Financialinstitution) Dermot Desmond 1.6 (Glasgow Celtic,dominant shareholder) Shareholders United 1.0 (Activist group) Otherinvestment companies 16.8 Ordinary United fans 15.0 Others 5.9 To determine whether the club is owner or managerially controlled, we would need to consider the size of the largest stake, the distribution and size of other holdings including thedirectors’holdings,themotivationforholdingthesharesandthepropensitytovote.The club was owner-controlled when Martin Edwards was chief executive and the largest shareholder. There appeared to be a period when the company was managerially controlled when the board of directors controlled a small proportion of the shares and the largest shareholders were said to be investors rather than active owners. However, thatpositionappearstohavechangedwiththeemergenceofdominantshareholderswho maywish tocontrolthecompany. SYSTEMS OF CORPORATE CONTROL The di¡erences between countries in shareholder ownership patterns in£uence the nature of their corporate governance systems. According to Franks and Meyer (1992), there are fundamental di¡erences between the corporate control systems of the UK and the USA and France, Germany and Japan. The former they describe as outsider systems and the latter as insider systems. The characteristics that distinguish the systemsarelistedinTable1.3. Insidersystems Insider systems are characterized by relatively few quoted companies, concentrated ownership, dominance of corporate and/or institutional shareholders and reciprocal shareholding. Shares are infrequently traded, but when they are they often involve large blocks. Takeover activity is largely absent, and where mergers take place they are largely done by agreement. However, Vodafone did acquire Mannesmann 10 PART I g CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND BUSINESS OBJECTIVES Table1.3 Characteristicsofinsiderandoutsidersystems Characteristics UKandUSA EuropeandJapan Listedcompanies Many Few Tradingownership Frequent;liquidcapitalmarket Infrequent;illiquidcapitalmarket Inter-companyholdings Few Many Shares Widelyheld Largeholdings Dispersedindividuals Concentratedcompanies Financialinstitutions Concentrationof Low High ownership Source Author following a hostile bid. These characteristics, it is argued, lead to more active owner participation. Owners and other stakeholders are represented on the boards of companies, and there is active investor participation in controlling the company; this minimizes externalin£uencesinthecontrolofthecompany.Ownership lieswithinthe corporate sector rather than with a multiplicity of individual shareholders. Directors are representatives of other companies and interest groups, while a two-tier board structure allows a wider group of stakeholders to o¡er the company a broader spectrum of advice tending to reinforce longer term goals and stability for the company. Information about the ¢rm’s problems and performance is available more readily to corporate or institutional shareholders than to individual shareholders; this enables them be better informed about the ¢rm’s performance because they have insideinformation. Germany Germany is an example of an insider system. It has according to Franks and Meyer (2001) around 800 quoted companies compared with nearly 3,000 in the UK. Ownership is much more concentrated with 85% of the largest quoted companies having a single shareholder owning more than 25% of the voting shares. Large ownership stakes tend to rest in the hands of families or companies with inter- connected holdings. Where shares are more widely dispersed then the in£uence of banks is stronger: for example, the largest shareholder in BMW is the Quandt family which owns 46% of the voting equity. Stefan Quandt is one of four deputy chairmen, and his sister Susanne is a member of the supervisory board. Head of the family is Joanna Quandt, who is the majority owner of Altana, a pharmaceutical manufacturer; thismakesthem thecontrollersoftwo of Germany’stop 30companies(FinancialTimes 16 August 2002). The supervisory board appoints the management board. When the company’s acquisition of British Leyland was deemed unsuccessful the chairman of the management board and two other directors were quickly dismissed in early 1999 byinsideraction. CHAPTER 1 g OWNERSHIP CONTROL AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 11 Outsidersystems Outsider systems are characterized by dispersed share ownership, with the dominant owners being nonbank ¢nancial institutions and private individuals. Owners and other stakeholders are not represented on the boards of companies. Shareholders are seen as passive investors who only rarely question the way in which a company is being operated. Shares are easily sold and tend to be held for investment purposes, as part of a diversi¢ed portfolio, rather than for control purposes; this discourages active participation in company a¡airs since shares are easily traded. Thus, dissatisfaction with the performance of a company leads the shareholder to sell shares, rather than initiatemovestochangethemanagementorevencompanypolicies. Dispersed ownership is assumed to mean managerial control; this is particularly true when ¢nancial institutions hold numerous small stakes. While such institutional investors may have information advantages, they do not use this to in£uence management directly but to maintain the value of their investment portfolios on behalf of clients. The monitoring of managers is said to be superior in insider systems, with deteriorating performance more quickly acted on. In the outsider system, changing management and policies is a slower process and may involve the takeover ofthefailingbusinessbyotherenterprises. CONSTRAINTS ON MANAGERIAL DISCRETION The degree of discretion that senior executive managers have in setting objectives is limited by both external and internal constraints. External constraints arise from the active market in company shares while internal constraints arise from the role of non- executive board members and stakeholders, trying to align the managers’ and the owners’interestsbytherulesshapingcorporategovernance. Externalconstraints Thereare¢ve sourcesof externalconstraintonmanagerial behaviour inany systemof corporatecontrol.Thosewhopotentiallyholdthispowerare: g Holders of large blocks of shares who use or threaten to use their voting power to changemanagementortheirpoliciesiftheybecomedissatis¢ed. g Acquirers of blocks of shares sold by existing shareholders unhappy with the performanceofmanagement. g Bidders in the takeover process who promise to buy all the voting shares of the enterprise. g Debtors/Investors,particularlyintimesof¢nancialdistress,whoacttoprotecttheir interestsinthecompany. g Externalregulatorsandauditors.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.