JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jebo (cid:2) Building and rebuilding trust with promises and apologies EricSchnitera,∗,RomanM.Sheremetab,DanielSznycerc aEconomicScienceInstitute,ChapmanUniversity,OneUniversityDrive,Orange,CA92866,UnitedStates bArgyrosSc hoolof Businessa ndEcono mics,Chapm an University, OneU niversity Dr ive,Ora nge,CA 92866,UnitedStates cCenterfo rEvolu ti onaryPsy chol ogy,Univer sityofCali fornia,Sant aBa rbara,CA9 3106, UnitedS tate s a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t Articlehistory: Usingtrustgames,westudyhowpromisesandmessagesareusedtobuildnewtrustwhere Receiv ed14May2012 itdidn otpr eviousl yex istan dtor ebuilddam ag edtrust.In the sega m es,tru stees mad enon- Accepted 8 S epte mber 2012 bi ndi ngp romiseso finve stm en t-contin gentretu rns,t he ninve storsd ecidedw heth erto Available online 14 September 2012 invest,andfinallytrusteesdecidedhowmuchtoreturn.Afteranunexpectedsecondgame wasannounced,butbeforeitcommenced,trusteescouldsendaone-waymessage.This Keywords: designallowedustoobservetheendogenousemergenceandnaturaldistributionoftrust- Promise relevantbehaviorsandfocusonnaturallyoccurringremedialstrategiesusedbypromise- Atonement Apology breakersanddistrustedtrustees,theireffectsoninvestors,andsubsequentoutcomes.Inthe Cheaptalk firstgame16.6%oftrusteesweredistrustedand18.8%oftrustedtrusteesbrokepromises. Cheapsignals Trusteesdistrustedinthefirstgameusedlongmessagesandpromisesclosertoequal Trustgame splitstoencouragetrustinthesecondgame.Torestoredamagedtrust,promise-breakers Trust building used apo logiesand upgr ad edp romise s.On ave rage,in vestment sinea chgamepaidoff Reme dial strategies forin vestorsan dtru stees,sug gestingtha tef fectiveus eofcheapsi gna lsfos tersp rofita ble Reciprocity trust-basedexchangeintheseeconomies. Experiments © 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Inmoderneconomies,wheretrustrealizesvastamountsofpotentialgainsintransactionsinvolvingdeferredorrisky returns,problemsassociatedwithdevelopingandrestoringtrustareparticularlyrelevant.Ascientificunderstandingof the processes that encourage trust where it did not previously exist and restore trust when it is damaged is therefore ofparamountimportance.Despitethelargeliteratureondamagestocorporatereputation(e.g.seeBarnett,2003onUS chemicalindustrydisasters;seeRobinsonandRousseau,1994forasurveyofcorporatetrustviolations),verylittleresearch existsonhownewtrustcanbeencouragedwhereitdidnotpreviouslyexistandhowdamagedtrustcanberebuilt(Dirks etal.,2009).Mostoftheexistingresearchinthisarea(butseeFischbacherandUtikal,2010)iseitherexclusivelytheoretical (Lewicki and Bunker, 1996; Mishra, 1996; Lewicki and Wiethoff, 2000; Ren and Gray, 2009; Gillespie and Dietz, 2009), based on anecdotal or archival evidence (Elsbach, 1994; Knight and Pretty, 1999), surveys (Slovic, 1993), diary studies (ConwayandBriner,2002),fictionalvignettes(Tomlinsonetal.,2004),videotapeddramatizations(Kimetal.,2004,2006), (cid:2) ForinspirationtopursuethisstudywethankJohnDickhaut.Wethankanadvisoryeditorandananonymousrefereefortheircomments.Helpful commentswerealsoreceivedfromHillyKaplan,WojtekPrzepiorka,andparticipantsattheWorkshoponCommunicationinGames(attheUniversityof Zurich),theHumanBehaviorandEvolutionSocietyannualmeeting(inMontpellier,France),theCenterforEvolutionaryPsychology(atUCSantaBarbara), theJohnDickhautMemorialConference(atChapmanUniversity),andtheAssociationforReligion,EconomicsandCultureannualmeeting(atChapman University).WewouldalsoliketothanktheEconomicScienceInstituteatChapmanUniversityforfundingthisresearch. ∗ Correspondingauthor. E-mailaddress:[email protected](E.Schniter). 0167-2681/$–seefrontmatter© 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2012.09.011 E.Schniteretal./JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 243 orexperimentaldesignsusingdeception(Gibsonetal.,1999;Bottometal.,2002;NakayachiandWatabe,2005;Schweitzer etal.,2006;OhtsuboandWatanabe,2009). To study how damaged trust can be rebuilt and new trust can be encouraged, we conducted a non-deceptive study whereinfinanciallymotivatedparticipantsusedendogenouslycreatedandnaturallydistributedpromisesandapologies. Ourstudyisbasedonaversionofthe“investmentgame”byBergetal.(1995).Intheoriginalinvestmentgameaninvestoris endowedwith$10andcaninvestanyportionofherendowmentbysendingittoatrustee.Theamountsenttriplesinvalue beforereachingthetrustee.Havingreceivedfundsfromthistripledinvestment,thetrusteecanreciprocatebyreturning anyportionofthesefundstotheinvestor.Sincesendingmoneyisrisky,investmentsareusuallyinterpretedastrust,and sinc ereturn ing mone yisco stl y,re ciprocati onvia returnso ninves tm entsi sinterpreted ase vidence oftrustwor thi ness.1 The investmentgame,therefore,hasbeenextensivelyusedtostudytrustandreciprocityinaninvestmentsetting(forareview seeOstromandWalker,2005).Acommonfindingintheliteratureisthatinvestorstendtoexhibittrustandtrusteestendto reciprocate.Ithasalsobeenwellestablishedthatpre-playcommunication,evenif“irrelevant”togamestrategy,caninduce highercontributionsinpublicgoodsgames(formeta-analysesseeSally,1995;Balliet,2010)andmorecooperationindyadic socialdilemmas(Deutsch,1958,1960;RadlowandWeidner,1966;Buchanetal.,2006;DuffyandFeltovich,2006;Bracht andFeltovich,2009).However,withtheexceptionofafewstudiesusingdeception,theexperimentaleconomicliterature is silent as to what behavior ensues when promises fail to establish trust and what happens to trust and reciprocity in subsequentinteractionsafterpromisesarebrokenandtrustisdamaged. Inthispaperwedescribeastudyusingtrustgamesthatexamineshowpromisesandmessagesareusedtobuildnew trustwhereitdidnotpreviouslyexistandtorebuilddamagedtrust.Inthesegames,trusteesmadenon-bindingpromisesof investment-contingentreturns,theninvestorsdecidedwhethertoinvest,andfinallytrusteesdecidedhowmuchtoreturn. Afteranunexpectedsecondgamewasannounced,butbeforeitcommenced,trusteescouldsendaone-waymessage.This designallowedustoobservetheendogenousemergenceandnaturaldistributionoftrust-relevantbehaviorsandfocuson naturallyoccurringremedialstrategiesusedbypromise-breakersanddistrustedtrustees,theireffectsoninvestors,and subsequentoutcomes.Inthefirstgame16.6%oftrusteesweredistrustedand18.8%oftrustedtrusteesbrokepromises. Trusteesdistrustedinthefirstgameusedpromisesclosertoequalsplitsand–comparedtopreviouslytrustedpromise- keepers–relativelylongermessagestoencouragenewtrustinthesecondgame.Promise-breakersusedrelativelyhigher newpromises(comparedtoallothertrustees)andmessages(usuallywithapology)tosuccessfullyrestoredamagedtrust. Onaverage,investmentsineachgamepaidoffforinvestorsandtrustees,suggestingthatthecontext-specificsignaling describedabove,canfosterprofitabletrust-basedexchangesintheseeconomies. 2. Background Whilemutuallybeneficialnon-bindingagreementshelprealizeopportunitiestogainfromasynchronoustrade,theyare subjecttoexploitationbyunder-reciprocatorsornon-reciprocators.Ourresearchfocusesontrustees’cueandsignaleffects oninvestortrustinasynchronousexchangesthatprovideopportunityformutualadvantage.Intheseexchanges,wedefine trustasvoluntarilycedingresourcestoanotherintheexpectationthattheotherintendstoreciprocateinaccordancewith signaledintentions.Trustworthinessisdefinedasreciprocation(ofresourcescededbytheinvestor)inaccordancewith signaledintentions. To successfully navigate a trust-based cooperative interaction and avoid exploitation by cheaters, it is important for investorstoobtainaccurateinformationabouttheabilityandwillingness(propensity)oftrusteestocarryouttheirend ofthecooperativedeal.Trustworthyreputationsthathavebeendemonstratedbypastactionsserveasreliablecuesupon whichinvestorscanmaketrust-baseddecisions.Intheinitialinteractionswithunknownpartners,informativecuesabout aninvestor’swillingnesstotrustoratrustee’strustworthinessareunavailable.Intheabsenceofinformationaboutthe int eractants’ pastbehavio r, signal s2 ar eoftense nttoreceiversw ith theintention t oco mmunica te information about the sender(e.g.seeFarrellandRabin,1996);forexample,thatthesenderistrustworthy.Wherecueshaveinformedinvestorsof untrustworthiness,signalsmaybesentwiththeintentionofpersuadingthoseinvestorsthatthesenderismoretrustworthy thaninferredfromthosecuesalone. Signalsencouragingtrustappeartobeimportanttoolsfordevelopingmutuallybeneficialrelationshipsunderconditions wheretrusthasnotyetbeenestablishedandwheretrusthasbeendamaged.Withouttheeffectiveuseofsignalscooperative 1 Thisinterpretationisbasedontheassumptionthatparticipantsidentifyandactinaccordancewithunstatedif–thenpropositionsandexpectotherstoas well(Rousseau,1989),thoughthereisnocontractstatingexpectedorcontingentbehaviorintheclassic“investmentgame”(seeBergetal.,1995).Because theassertionthattheoriginalgamewasuniversallyunderstoodtobeabout“trust”wasdebatable,JohnDickhautpreferredcallingitthe“investment game”–asitisintheBergetal.(1995)article.Byaddinganewstartingstagetothegamewheretrusteesmakepromisestoreturnaportionofincome frominvestment–thisgamebecomesagamemoreexplicitlyabouttrust.Forthisreasonwerefertoourmodifiedformoftheclassicinvestmentgame, describedbelow,asa“trustgame.” 2 Wedi stinguis h cu esfro msignalsfromcoercion(borrowingfromsimilardefinitionsbyDiggleetal.,2007;Scott-Phillips,2008)asfollows.Cue.Any behaviororfeaturethat(i)affectsthebehaviorofotherorganisms;(ii)whichiseffectivebecausetheeffecthasevolvedtobeaffectedbythebehavioror feature;butwhich(iii)didnotevolve.Signal.Anybehaviororfeaturethat(i)affectsthebehaviorofotherorganisms;(ii)evolvedbecauseofthoseeffects; and(iii)whichiseffectivebecausetheeffect(theresponse)hasevolvedtobeaffectedbythebehaviororfeature.Coercion.Anybehaviororfeaturethat (i)affectsthebehaviorofotherorganisms;(ii)evolvedbecauseofthoseeffects;butwhich(iii)iseffectiveforsomereasonotherthanthattheeffecthas evolvedtobeaffectedbythebehaviororfeature. 244 E.Schniteretal./JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 interactionsmaybeforegone:potentialinvestorsmaydecidenottoextendtrustwhentheylackreputationalinformation andwhencuesindicateabreachoftrust.Further,whentrusthasbeendamaged,signalsgiveinvestorsaccesstorelevant thoughinvisiblepropensitiesoftrustees,suchasinthecaseofrecalibratedupgradesintrustworthiness.Thisistruewhether trusthasbeendamagedintentionallyorunintentionally(AxelrodandDion,1988). Althoughsignalsthataccuratelyconveybehavioralpropensitiesarepotentiallyusefultobothsendersandreceivers, signalersmaysend“dishonestsignals”tobenefitattheexpenseofreceivers.Criticalreceiverscanincurlowercoststhan naïvereceivers(DawkinsandKrebs,1978;Maynard-Smith,1982),andsonaturalselectionfavorsthosereceiverswhocan accuratelyassessthecost–benefittradeoffsassociatedwithemitters’signals,andcalibratetheirtrustfulnessaccordingly. Zahavi(1975)addressedthequestionof“whyaresignalsreliable?”suggestingthatthehighproductioncostofasignal guaranteesitsreliability,insofarastheproductioncostoutweighsthebenefitsgainedfromusingthesignaldeceptively, butnotfromusingithonestly.Theprototypicalexampleisthemassiveandcolorfulpeacock’stail,indexingthepeacock’s geneticqualityforpeahens’mateselection(Petrieetal.,1991).Inthissystem,costlysignalspersuadethereceiverswhile cheapsignalsfailtodoso(Zahavi,1993;Grafen,1990). Productioncostsarenottheonlywarrantorsofsignalreliability,however.Humanlanguage,whetherspokenorwrit- ten,isanarbitrarycommunicationsystemthatoftenusesrelativelycheap-to-producesignalstonegotiatetrustbetween individualswithconflictinginterests(Lachmannetal.,2001).Ifthesecheapsignalsareusedbyandrelieduponbyhumans globallyandonaverage,whatexplainsthemaintenanceoftheirreliability? Thereliabilityofcheapsignalsissupportedbytheactualityorthreatofsocialsanctionsthatcanmorethanoffsetthe short-termbenefitsofcheatinganddeception(Rohwer,1977;Kiyonarietal.,2000;Mascletetal.,2003).Aselectiveregime characterizedbyrepeatedinteractionsamongknownothers(Kelly,1995)hasledtopsychologicalmechanismsforsocial exchangethatbalance(i)thecostsofmistakingaone-shotinteractionforarepeatedinteractionwith(ii)thefargreater costsofmistakingarepeatedinteractionforaone-shotinteraction(Deltonetal.,2011).Hence,participantsinexplicitlyone- shotanonymousexperimentsoftenbehaveasiftheyexpectrepeatedinteractionswithtrustworthy,intrinsicallyvaluable partners(e.g.seeHoffmanetal.,1996;Kiyonarietal.,2000). Whilethesanctioningoffalsesignalsandourtendencytoerrtocautionmayreducethefrequencyoffalsesignalsina population,thoseindividualswhoexpecttoescapesanctionsmaybemoremotivatedtousesignalsdeceptively.Ineconomies whereopportunitycostsofforgonetrust-basedexchangearelarger,receiverstendtotolerategreaterproportionsoffalse signalstohonestsignals.Specifically,thelogicoferrormanagementtheory(forareviewseeHaseltonandNettle,2006) predictsthatdespitetheexistenceoffalsesignalingandthecostsofreceivingfalsesignals,signalswilltendtobereceived whenopportunitycostsassociatedwithnotreceivingtruesignalsoftrustworthiness(fromforgoneadvantageousexchange) aregreaterthancostsassociatedwithreceivingfalsesignalsoftrustworthiness(i.e.whentheconsequentexchangeproduces aloss).Thiseconomicallyjustifiedtoleranceofarateoffalsesignalingalsopredictsthatindividualswillexploitopportunities tousedeception.Thisstudyexplorestheuseofcheapsignals(e.g.promisesofreciprocation,personalizedmessages,and apologies)thatdonotdirectlyaffectpayoffsofthegame,orrequiremonetarycostsforproduction,yetarecommonfeatures oftrust-basedinteractions.Personalizedcommunicationmayimprovecooperation(Orbelletal.,1988;BohnetandFrey, 1999;Ridingsetal.,2002;Zhengetal.,2002;Buchanetal.,2006)byfacilitatingcoordination,decreasingsocialdistance, raisingsolidarity,andprovidingthecuesoffamiliaritythatarenormallyassociatedwithtrustworthyrelationships.Non- bindingpromiseshavealsobeenshowntoincreasecooperation(RubinandBrown,1975;KerrandKaufman-Gilliland,1994; ElingsenandJohannesson,2004;CharnessandDufwenberg,2006).Inrelationshipswheretrusthasbeendamaged,apologies andexplanationshavebeenshowntoelicitforgiveness(Ohbuchietal.,1989;Tavuchis,1991;LewickiandBunker,1996; BenoitandDrew,1997;GirardandMullet,1997;McCulloughetal.,1997,1998;Girardetal.,2002;Witvlietetal.,2002)and promotefuturetrust(DeCremeretal.,2010).Thesestrategiesarebasedonsignalsthatarecheaptoproduce,raisingthe questionsofhowpeopleusesignalsinthesecontexts;whenthesignalsachievetheirintendedeffects;andwhobenefits fromtheiruse. Insum,whilecheapsignalsarehelpfulforbuildingnewtrustandrebuildingdamagedtrusttoachieveefficientout- comes,theycanbeuseddeceptivelyandmaybedistrusted,makingtheirreliabilitytenuous.Therefore,weexpectthat inourexperimenttrusteeswhoseactionshavealreadyproducedreliablecuesestablishingtheirtrustworthyreputations (bykeepingpromisesandnotsuccumbingtomoreprofitableopportunism)willbelessincentivized(thanpreviouslydis- trustedtrustees,ortrusteeswhosereputationsindicateuntrustworthiness)tospendtimeandeffortconstructingmessages topersuadeinvestorstotrustthem,whenthosemessagesmightbedistrusted.Previouslydistrustedtrusteeswhohave notestablishedtrustworthinessanduntrustworthytrustees(i.e.promise-breakers)areexpectedtomakeuseofpromises andmessagesinanattempttoaffectinvestors’decisionstotrust.Wealsoexpectthatwhenusedand“working”toaffect investors’trust,signalsconveyingatrustworthypropensitywillprovidebenefitstobothinvestorandtrusteeonaverage. 3. Experimentaldesignandprocedures TheexperimentwasconductedatChapmanUniversity’sESIlaboratory.458participants(229pairs)wererecruitedfrom astandardcampus-widesubjectpoolforparticipationinanexperimentthatcouldlastupto45min.Participantsinteracted witheachotheranonymouslyoveralocalcomputernetwork.Theexperiment,whichlastedanaverageof35mintotaland didnotinvolvedeception,proceededasfollows.Uponarrival,participantsintheexperimentweretoldthattheywould receive$7forparticipation,tobepaidattheendoftheexperiment.Participantsthenreceivedinstructions(seeAppendixA) E.Schniteretal./JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 245 forasingletrustgamewith(i)noindicationofasubsequentgametofollowand(ii)nopromisesthattheexperimentwould endatconclusionofthatgame. Participantswereassignedtooneoftworoles:“ParticipantA”(investor),or“ParticipantB”(trustee).First,thetrustee completedthefollowingstandardizedstatement(whichwewillrefertobelowasapromise)byselectinganaturalnumber amountfrom0to20:“I(ParticipantB)promisetotransferback$ ofmyincometoyou(ParticipantA)ifyouchooseIN”. Thisstatementwasnotbinding,however.Thatis,thetrusteewasnotobligatedtotransferbacktheamountpromisedtothe investor,andbothtrusteeandinvestorknewthis.Thecomputerconveyedthetrustee’sstatementtotheinvestorandthen theinvestorchoseeitherOUTorIN.IftheinvestorchoseOUT,shereceived$5andthetrustee$0.IftheinvestorchoseIN, thenthetrusteereceived$20(the“income”),afterwhichheselectedawholedollaramountfrom$0to$20tosendbackto theinvestor. Afterthefirsttrustgame(Game1)finished,participantsweregiveninstructions(seeAppendixA)indicatingthatasecond trustgame(Game2)wouldfollow.InGame2,participantsweretoldtheywouldremaininthesamerolesandinteractwith thesamepartnerasinGame1.However,priortoGame2,thetrusteewasgivenanopportunitytouseatextboxtosenda one-waymessagetotheinvestor.Trusteesweretoldthat“inthesemessages,nooneisallowedtoidentifyhimorherselfby name,number,gender,orappearance,”butthatotherthantheserestrictions,trusteescould“sayanythinginthemessage.” Iftrusteeswishednottosendamessagetheywereinstructedto“simplyclickonthesendbuttonwithouthavingtyped anythinginthemessagebox.”Thecomputerconveyedthetrustee’smessageandsubsequentlythestandardizedpromise totheinvestor,andthenGame2proceeded.WespecifiedthatGame2,whichhadthesamerulesasGame1,wasthelast an dfin alpartof the expe riment ( i.e.therewo uld benosub sequ entga m es).3 Therewere25experimentalsessions.Eachsessionhadbetween10and24participants.Theaverageexperimentalearn- ingswere$18,rangingfroma$0to$40,plus$7forarrivingtotheexperimentontimeandparticipating.Noparticipant participatedmorethanonce,andnoparticipanthadpriorexperiencewithasimilargameenvironment. 4. Results 4.1. Game1 Weexpectthattrustees,awareofinvestorself-interestandmotivesforcriticalsignalreception,wouldpromiseinvestors transfersofatleast$6(minimallyhigherthanthepayofftotheinvestorifhechoosesOUT)butlessthan$20(whichwould providenobenefittothepromise-maker).Twoplausiblefocalpointsforpromisedreturnamountsarethemidpointofthe $6–$19range,$12.5(thoughonlywholedollaramountslike$12or$13couldbechosen),andtheeven-splitof$10.Wary thattrustees’mayhavelessincentivetohonorpromisescloserto$20thantotheeven-splitamountof$10,wealsoexpect thatinvestorsshouldbemoresuspiciousoftheveracityofhigherpromisesandthereforelesslikelytoinvestinhigher promises.Iftheminderrstocaution,aswehavesuggested,andinterpretstheone-shotgameaspotentiallyrepeatable, trusteeswhohavebeentrustedshouldreciprocateenoughto,atminimum,provideinvestorsprofitablereturnsontheir investments.Thesepredictionsstandinstarkcontrasttotherational(non-cooperative)choicepredictionsthatexpectnon- bindingpromisestohavenoeffectoninvestors.Accordingtorationalchoicetheory,trusteeswhoreceiveincomesshould returnnothing(despitewhattheymayhavepromised)and,basedonthis,investorsshouldalwayschoosetonotinvest (regardlessofthepromisetheyreceived). Fig.1displaystheaggregatedistributionofinvestmentandpromise-keepingdecisionsintheexperiment,whileFig.2 displaysthedistributionofpromisesmadebytrusteesinGame1.InGame1,trusteesonaveragepromisedtoreturn$9.20 (SD=2.38)outof$20and83.4%(191/229)ofinvestorschoseIN. FirstweevaluatethedistributionsofGame1promisesassociatedwithtrustinganddistrustingdecisions,respectively, andhowtheseinvestmentdecisionsaffectedinvestorandtrusteeearnings.ThedistributionofpromisesinFig.2indicates that investors who chose IN received promises in the range of $6–$19 (99% of the time), with promises of $12 or $13 relativelyuncommon(1%ofthetime),andthepromiseof$10mostcommon(morethan50%ofthetime).Investorswho choseOUTreceivedlowerpromisesonaverage(i.e.M =$8.61(SD =4.33)versusM =$9.31(SD =1.75);Wilcoxonrank- 1 1 2 2 sumtest,p-value=0.01,n =191,n =38),and,comparedtotrustedpromises,receivedeitherrelativelyloworrelatively 1 2 highpromisesoverall.Toconfirmthisobservation,weestimateprobitmodels(seeTable1,specifications1and2),wherethe dependentvariableistheinvestmentdecisioninGame1andtheindependentvariablesaredummyvariablesforpromises less than $9 and greater than $11, as well as the amounts of these promises. In specification (1), the dummy variables arenegativeandsignificant,indicatingthatinvestorsarelesslikelytoinvestwhenpromisesareeitherrelativelylowor relativelyhigh.Moreover,specification(2)indicatesthat,amongpromiseslowerthan$9,thereisapositivecorrelation betweentheamountpromisedandtheprobabilityofinvestment.Ontheotherhand,amongpromiseshigherthan$11, thereisanegativecorrelationbetweentheamountpromisedandtheprobabilityofinvestment.Inotherwords,promises closertotheeven-splitof$10elicitahigherrateofINresponses. 3 Aftereachtrustgameparticipantswerealsoaskedtofillouta20itemsurveyinwhichtheyreportedtheiremotionalstatesconsequentontheir decisions,gameinteractions,andresultingoutcomes.Analysisanddiscussionofthemediatingrolesofemotionsarenotincludedinthispaper. 246 E.Schniteretal./JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 Fig.1. AggregatedistributionofdecisionsinGames1and2. InGame1,investmentyieldedgreaterpayoffsthannon-investmentforbothinvestorsandtrustees.Investorswhochose IN received back $8.19 on average, which is more than their original endowment of $5 (Wilcoxon signed rank test, p- value<0.01, n=191). Trusted trustees earned an average of $11.81, more than the $0 of distrusted trustees (Wilcoxon rank-sumtest,p-value<0.01,n =38,n =191).TheOLSestimationofspecifications(3)and(4)inTable1indicatesthatthe 1 2 amountreturnedbytrusteeiscorrelatedwiththeamountpromised.Specifically,specification(3)indicatesthatbothlow andhighpromisesarefollowedbylowerreturnedamounts.Moreover,specification(4)indicatesthatamountreturned increasesasitgetsclosertotheeven-splitpromiseof$10.Theseresultssupporttherationaleforwhyinvestorsreceiving especiallyhighorlowpromisesshouldtendtochooseOUT. FortheinvestorswhochoseIN,themeanamountreturnedof$8.19wassignificantlylowerthanthemeantrustedpromise of$9.31(Wilcoxonsignedranktest,p-value<0.01,n =n =191).Despitemeanreturnsbeinglowerthanpromised,wefind 1 2 thatpromisestendedtobeveridical:81.2%oftrustedpromises(155/191)werekept(i.e.theamountreturnedwasequalto orgreaterthanthepromise),and18.8%(36/191)werebroken(i.e.theamountreturnedwaslessthanthepromise).Below weusetheterms“promise-keepers”and“promise-breakers”torefertotrustedtrusteeswhoexactlymetorexceededtheir IN 83.4% OUT 16.6% 100 30 0 9 0 8 0 7 0 2 cy 0 cy n 6 n e e u 0 u q 5 q e e Fr 40 Fr 0 0 1 3 0 2 0 1 0 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 P rom ise Prom ise Fig.2. DistributionofpromisesinGame1(resultinginINorOUT). E.Schniteretal./JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 247 Table1 Game1determinantsofinvestmentandreturn. Dependentvariable Invest1 Invest1 Return1 Return1 Specification (1)Probit (2)Probit (3)OLS (4)OLS Promise1<9 −0.83*** −4.81*** −1.77*** −6.92** [dummyforpromiseslessthan9inGame1] (0.21) (1.07) (0.41) (2.77) Promise1< 9× Promise1 0.60*** 0.72* [amountpromisedinGame1forpromises<9] (0.16) (0.38) Promise1> 11 −1.01** 8.44 −4.52*** 12.30* [dummyforpromisesgreaterthan11inGame1] (0.41) (5.19) (0.95) (6.62) Promise1> 11× Promise1 −0.55 * −1.11** [amountpromisedinGame1forpromises>11] (0.30) (0.43) Constant 1.35*** 1.35*** 8.81*** 8.81*** (0.15) (0.15) (0.21) (0.21) Observations 229 229 191 191 Standarderrorsinparenthesis. * Significantat10%. ** Significant at 5%. *** Significant at 1%. promisedamounts,andwhoreturnedlessthantheirpromisedamounts(whetherthereturnsweremonetarilyprofitable totheinvestorsornot),respectively. 4.2. Game2 Whilecheapsignalsaremanipulatedbytrustees,affectinvestors,andprovidenetbenefitstobothinvestorsandtrusteesin Game1,facilitatingprofitabletrust-basedexchangeswherepreviousreputationshadnotbeenestablished,Game2provides usarelativelydifferentgameenvironmentinwhichtostudycheapsignals.InGame2,reputationshavebeenestablished formanyinvestorsandtrustees–raisingthequestionofwhethertheuseofcheapsignalswillstillmatterwherecuesof trustingandtrustworthybehavior(oritsabsence)areavailable. InGame2,trusteespromisedtoreturn$9.79onaverage,ahigheramountthanthemeanof$9.20promisedinGame 1(Wilcoxonsignedranktest,p-value<0.01,n=229).Game2promisesresultedin87.3%(200/229)ofinvestorschoosing IN,onlyslightlymorethanthe83.4%(191/229)ofINdecisionsmadeinGame1(Fisher’sexacttest,p-value=0.59,n=229). TrusteereputationasestablishedinGame1andthenewpromisesissuedinGame2affectedinvestmentdecisionsinGame 2.Thee stimationo fp robitmodel s( specifi ca tion s1 and2 inTable 2)4ind ica testh at bothpro mise-break inginGam e 1and promiseslowerthantheeven-splitinGame2elicitedlessinvestmentdecisionsinGame2.Overall,theinvestmentsmadein Game2paidoff.InvestorswhochoseINreceivedback$8.73onaverage,whichismorethantheOUTpayoffof$5(Wilcoxon signedranktest,p-value<0.01,n=200).Trustedtrusteesearnedanaverageof$11.27,morethanthe$0ofdistrustedtrustees (Wilcoxonrank-sumtest,p-value<0.01,n =29,n =200).Theestimationofspecifications(3)and(4)inTable2indicates 1 2 thathigherpromisesinGame1,agreaterextentofunder-returnrelativetopromiseinGame1,andunevensplitpromises inGame2allpredictloweramountsreturnedinGame2.Overall,andsimilartoGame1,promisesinGame2tendedto beveridical;75%ofpromises(150/200)werekeptorexceeded,and25.0%(50/200)werebroken.Inthesectionsbelowwe furtherexploretheeffectsofpromisesandmessagesonGame2investmentsandearningsacrossdifferent“types”ofdyads aggregatedbyGame1decisions. 4.2.1. Promise-keepers Forthesubsetof155Game1promise-keepingtrustees,weobservehigheraveragepromisesinGame2.Fig.3displays thedistributionofGame2promisesresultinginINandOUTmadebythesepromise-keepers.Overall,thissetoftrustees promisedtoreturnanaverageof$9.46inGame2,whichishigherthantheiraveragepromiseof$9.02inGame1(Wilcoxon signedranktest,p-value<0.01,n =n =155). 1 2 Perhapsasaconsequenceofpromise-keepers’demonstratedtrustworthinessinGame1,theGame2investmentrate of92.3%(143/155)inGame1promise-keeperswashigherthantheoverallinvestmentrateof83.4%(191/229)inGame1 (Fisher’sexacttest,p-value<0.01,n =155,n =229).Specifications(1)and(2)inTable3indicatethatmessageswithcontent 1 2 andprom isesc lose rtothe ev ensp lito f$10 pos itivel yaffectedinve stm ent in pr omise -k eepers.5 4 In estimation of Table 2, we have excluded variables corresponding to the amount promised in Game 1 (i.e. Promise1<9×Promise1 and Promis e1>11×Pro mis e1),si nce the sevar iablesare highlycor relatedwithret urn s.Ne verthele ss,evenwh en these var iable sareinclu d e d theestim ates inTable2areverysimilar. 5 Note t hat ines timatingtheseregressionswecannotincludebothreturnsinGame1andpromisesinGame1sinceforpromise-keeperstheyare perfectly corr ela ted.Moreov er,we hadtoomi tva riableP romise2 >11× Promise 2s inceth e rear eonlythr ee observ at ionsg reat erthan$11,whic hma kes Promise2 >11andPro mise2>11 ×Pr omis e2 almo stperfec tlycorrela t ed. 248 E.Schniteretal./JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 Table2 Game2determinantsofinvestmentandreturn. Dependentvariable Invest2 Invest2 Return2 Return2 Specification (1)Probit (2)Probit (3)OLS (4)OLS Promise1<9 −0.05 −0.07 −0.85 −0.97 [dummyforpromiseslessthan9inGame1] (0.36) (0.36) (0.79) (0.78) Promise1> 11 −0.37 −0.21 2.67* 1.73 [dummyforpromisesgreaterthan11inGame1] (0.65) (0.70) (1.45) (1.47) Return1 0.00 −0.02 0.02 0.03 [returninGame1] (0.12) (0.12) (0.26) (0.26) Broken1 −0.80 * −0.84 * 0.86 1.86 [brokenpromiseinGame1] (0.48) (0.49) (1.33) (1.36) Broken1× (Promise 1-R eturn1) −0.07 −0.10 −0.58 * −0.64** [extentofunder-returnrelativetoGame1promise] (0.11) (0.12) (0.30) (0.30) Distrusted 1 −0.22 −0.32 −1.53 −1.35 [nottrustedinGame1] (1.06) (1.10) (2.39) (2.38) Promis e2<9 −1.37 *** −2.13 ** −1.66 ** −1.47 [dummyforpromiseslessthan9inGame2] (0.32) (0.88) (0.74) (2.79) Promise2< 9× Promise2 0.11 −0.01 [amountpromisedinGame2forpromises<9] (0.12) (0.38) Promise2> 11 −0.14 2.20 0.78 −12.01** [dummyforpromisesgreaterthan11inGame2] (0.42) (1.90) (1.05) (4.64) Promise2> 11× Promise2 −0.14 0.80*** [amountpromisedinGame1forpromises>11] (0.11) (0.28) Constant 2.05* 2.26* 8.98*** 8.83*** (1.13) (1.17) (2.51) (2.48) Observations 229 229 200 200 Standarderrorsinparenthesis. * Significantat10%. ** Significant at 5%. *** Significant at 1%. Weexpectedthat,duetothegreaterreliabilityofavailablebehavioralcueswhichdemonstratedtheirtrustworthiness (relativetothereliabilityofacheapsignal),Game1promise-keeperswouldbelessinclinedthanpromise-breakersand distrustedtrusteestoconstructmessagesforthepurposeofpersuadinginvestorstochooseINinGame2,andsowould sendbothshortermessagesandahigherproportionofemptymessagesinGame2.Supportingthatexpectation,Game 1promise-keepers’messagescontainedfewerwordsthanthosefromthesetincludingbothGame1distrustedtrustees andGame1promise-breakers(M =11.41(SD =11.94)versusM =22.9(SD =22.37);Wilcoxonrank-sumtest,p<0.01, 1 1 2 2 n =155,n =74).Game1promise-keepers’messageswerealsomorefrequentlyemptythanthosefromthesetofboth 1 2 Game1distrustedtrusteesandGame1promise-breakers(20.6%versus10.8%ofthetime;Fisher’sexacttest,p-value=0.05, n=229). InvestmentsinGame1promise-keeperspaidoffforinvestorschoosingINinGame2.Theseinvestorsreceivedanaverage of$8.62fromtrustees,asopposedtothe$5earnedfromOUT(Wilcoxonsignedranktest,p-value<0.01,n=143),with83.9% IN 92.3% OUT 7.7% 100 30 0 9 0 8 0 7 0 2 cy 0 cy n 6 n e e u 0 u q 5 q e e Fr 40 Fr 0 0 1 3 0 2 0 1 0 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Prom ise Pr omis e Fig.3. DistributionofpromisesinGame2(resultinginINorOUT)byGame1promise-keepers. E.Schniteretal./JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 249 Table3 Game2determinantsofinvestmentandreturnwithGame1promise-keepers. Dependentvariable Invest2 Invest2 Return2 Return2 Specification (1)Probit (2)Probit (3)OLS (4)OLS Return1 0.15 0.11 −0.01 −0.05 [returninGame1] (0.15) (0.15) (0.21) (0.21) Message 0.63* 0.61 −0.24 −0.24 [messagewithcontent] (0.38) (0.38) (0.63) (0.63) Promise2<9 −1.12 *** −4.39 ** −2.23 *** −9.13 [dummyforpromiseslessthan9inGame2] (0.43) (2.21) (0.69) (5.57) Promise2< 9× Promise2 0.45 0.92 [amountpromisedinGame2forpromises<9] (0.30) (0.74) Promise2> 11 −1.83** −1.82 ** 9.12*** 9.08*** [dummyforpromisesgreaterthan11inGame2] (0.80) (0.81) (2.01) (2.00) Constant 0.29 0.63 9.23*** 9.58*** (1.42) (1.47) (2.04) (2.06) Observations 155 155 143 143 Standarderrorsinparenthesis. * Significantat10%. ** Significant at 5%. *** Significant at 1%. (120/143)ofthepromiseskeptorexceeded,and16.1%(23/143)broken.Comparedto$0earnedbythoseGame1promise- keepersthatwerenottrustedinGame2,promise-keepersalsoprofitedfromtrustedpromisesinGame2,earning$11.38 on average (Wilcoxon rank-sum test, p-value<0.01, n =12, n =143). Specifications (3) and (4) in Table 3 indicate that 1 2 Game2promiseslowerandhigherthantheeven-splitareassociatedwithlowerandhigheramountsreturnedbyGame1 promise-keepers,respectively.Whetherthemessageshavecontentornot,ontheotherhand,hasnoeffectonreturns. 4.2.2. Promise-breakers Amajorquestionourdataaddressconcernswhathappensafterabreachoftrustwhenafreshopportunityforcooperation arises:Howtrusteesbehave,howinvestorsrespond,andwhatoutcomesareachieved.Herewefocusonthe18.8%(36/191) ofpairswithbrokenpromisesinGame1(i.e.wheretheamountreturnedwaslowerthantheamountpromised).These brokenpromisesrepresentbreachesoftrustandtherelationshipsthatimmediatelyfollowareconsideredtohavedamaged trust(becausetrust-basedexpectationswerenotmet).Acentralquestionmotivatingthisstudyiswhethersignalssuchas newpromisesandapologiescan(i)restoreinvestors’willingnesstotrustand(ii)facilitatetheachievementofhigherjoint payoffs. Fig.4displaysthedistributionofpromisesmadeby36Game1promise-breakersinGame2resultinginINandOUT decisions.Promise-breakerspromised$12.11inGame2,whichissignificantlyhigherthantheiraveragepromiseof$10.58 inGame1(Wilcoxonsignedranktest,p-value=0.01,n =n =36).Theextentofupgradedpromises(Promise2–Promise1) 1 2 by promise-breakers is also significantly higher than the extent of upgraded promises by promise-keepers (M =1.53 1 (SD =3.70)versusM =0.44(SD =1.79);Wilcoxonrank-sumtest,p-value<0.01,n =36,n =155).Assumingthatmanyof 1 2 2 1 2 IN 69.4% OUT 30.6% 5 5 1 1 0 0 y 1 y 1 c c n n e e u u q q e e Fr Fr 5 5 0 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 Prom ise Prom ise Fig.4. DistributionofpromisesinGame2(resultinginINorOUT)byGame1promise-breakers. 250 E.Schniteretal./JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 Table4 Game2determinantsofinvestmentandreturnwithGame1promise-breakers. Dependentvariable Invest2 Invest2 Return2 Return2 Specification (1)Probit (2)Probit (3)OLS (4)OLS Return1 0.10 −0.11 0.69*** 1.15** [returninGame1] (0.08) (0.15) (0.24) (0.46) Promise2– Pr omise1 0.21* −0.46 [promiseadjustment] (0.13) (0.45) Promise1–R eturn1 −0.21* 0.46 [extentofunder-returnrelativetoGame1promise] (0.13) (0.45) Apology 1.88*** 1.88*** 2.69 2.69 [messagewithapology] (0.68) (0.68) (3.19) (3.19) Promise2 −0.09 0.13 0.37 −0.09 [amountpromisedinGame2] (0.12) (0.08) (0.48) (0.29) Constant −0.56 −0.56 −1.90 −1.90 (1.58) (1.58) (6.24) (6.24) Observations 36 36 25 25 Standarderrorsinparenthesis. * Significantat10%. ** Significant at 5%. *** Significant at 1%. theinvestorswhosetrusthadpreviouslybeendamagedwouldbeinclinedtochooseOUT,itappearsthatpromiseupgrades partiallyrestoretrust,since69.4%(25/36)ofinvestorswhosetrustwasdamagedinGame1choseINagain. Inadditiontopromiseupgrades,wealsofindthatGame1promise-breakersfrequentlyusedmessages.TableC1reportsall messagesthatweresentby36promise-breakers.Analyzingthemessages,wefindthat83.3%(30/36)ofthemessageshave somecon tent. 6 Gam e1 pro mi se-breakers’messa gescontai nm orewords th anm essa gesfro mGam e 1pr omise-kee pers (M =19.06 (SD =19.03) versus M =11.41 (SD =11.94); Wilcoxon rank-sum test, p-value=0.03, n =36, n =155), sug- 1 1 2 2 1 2 gestingthatthebehavioralcueoftrustworthinessmadeverbalpersuasionforcontinuedinvestmentlessdeterminantof re-investmentandlessnecessaryfortrustees. Tofurtherclassifyall36messages,weusedanincentivizedlaboratorycoordinationgame(HouserandXiao,2011).Three coder srecrui tedfrom th es ubjectpoo la ndbl ind tothehypo theses7 we reaskedtoc odeea chmess age twice :first based onwhetherornotitconformedtoa“broad”definitionofapology(anexplicitorimplicitacknowledgmentofoffense),and secondbasedonwhetherornotitconformedtoa“narrow”definitionofapology(anexplicitorimplicitacknowledgment ofoffense,alongwithremorse,regret,orsorrowstemmingfromacknowledgmentoftheoffense).All6messageswithout contentwerecodedbyallcodersasnotconformingtothebroaddefinitionandnotconformingtothenarrowdefinitionof apology.Ofthe30messageswithcontent,28werecodedbythemajorityofcodersasconformingtothebroaddefinitionof apology and 13 we recodedb ythe majorit yo fcode rsasc onf orm ingtoth en arrow de finitionofap ol ogy .8 Whenusingabroaddefinitionofapology,whichwascodedwith“substantial”agreement(Kappaof0.70),wefindthat 82.1%(23/28)ofapologizerswereretrustedinGame2incomparisontoonly25.0%(2/8)ofnon-apologizers(Fisher’sexact test,p-value<0.01,n=36),suggestingthatmessageswithapologyaremorelikelytorestoretrustafterbrokenpromises than emptym essag es o rm essageswit hout apology.9 Due tothelow er interr aterre lia bilityfo rmes sages coded according tothenarrowdefinition,wewillconsideronlythebroaddefinitionofapologyinthesubsequentanalyses. Thusfar,wehaveonlyconsideredtheindependenteffectsofnewpromisesandapologiesinrestoringdamagedtrust,but recognizethattheseremedialstrategiesareoftenusedjointly.AmongGame1promise-breakers,thesizeoftheupgradein amountpromisedissignificantlylargerforparticipantsissuingapologiesthanforthosewhodidnot(M =$1.68(SD =3.10) 1 1 versusM =$1(SD =5.55);Wilcoxonrank-sumtest,p-value=0.05,n =28,n =10).Whentheapologeticpromise-breakers 2 2 1 2 arecomparedtoallothertrusteesthedifferenceisevenlarger.Theupgradeinamountpromisedforapologetictrustees isalmostfourtimesgreaterthanamongallothertrustees(M =$1.68(SD =3.10)versusM =$0.44(SD =2.68);Wilcoxon 1 1 2 2 rank-sumtest,p-value=0.05,n =28,n =201),indicatingthatapologetictrusteesupgradedtheirpromisesmost. 1 2 Next,weestimateprobitregressions(seeTable4)toidentifyhowtheseremedialstrategiesworkinconjunction.Spec- ification (1) indicates that the two most significant predictors of trust in Game 2 are promise adjustments (specifically promiseupgrades)andapologies.Specification(2)showsthatinadditiontrustisnegativelyaffectedbytheextentofunder- 6 Wefindthat80%(24/30)ofmessageswithcontentrestoredtrust(i.e.whereinvestorschoseINinGame2afterhavingsufferedbrokenpromisesin Game1),asopposedtoonly16.7%(1/6)ofmessageswithoutcontent.Thesedifferencesaresignificant(Fisher’sexacttest,p-value<0.01,n=36). 7 Th ein st ructions for code rsand deta ils abouthow theyw erepaid areat tachedinA ppe ndixA.Cod erseach earne dan average o f$28 .3 3 formatched codings,plus$7forarrivingontimeandparticipating. 8 Weu seas tan da rdappro ach from con tentanalysismethodologytocalculateCohen’sKappainterrateragreementcoefficient(Cohen,1960;Krippendorff, 2004).Kappavaluesbetween0.41and0.60areconsidered“Moderate”agreement,andthoseabove0.60indicate“Substantial”agreement(LandisandKoch, 1977).WefindKappavaluesof0.70and0.53forthebroadandnarrowdefinitionsofapology,respectively. 9 Wh en using anarr owdefi ni tion ofap olog y,w hich wasc ode dwithm oderateag ree ment(Ka ppaof0.53),wefindthat84.6%(11/13)ofapologizerswere retrustedincomparisontoonly60.9%(14/23)ofnon-apologizers(Fisher’sexacttest,p-value=0.13,n=36). E.Schniteretal./JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization94 (2013) 242–256 251 return relative to Game 1 promise. Moreover, based on the likelihood-ratio test, we find that the promise adjustment, upgraded relative to the extent of under-return on previously broken promise (i.e. Promise2–(Promise1–Return1)), posi- tivelyandsignificantlyinfluencestrustinGame2(likelihood-ratiotest,p-value=0.05).Theseresultsindicatethatinvestors’ decisions to re-invest are sensitive not just to the existence of broken promises (specifications 1 and 2 in Table 2), but alsototheextentofunder-returnrelativetoGame1promise,apologies,andupgradedpromises(specifications1and2in Table4). Wehavearguedthatsignalssuchasapologiesandpromisesshouldhaveevolvedonlyiftheyprovidednetbenefitsto boththesendersandreceiversofthosesignalsonaverageandovertheevolutionofthecommunicationsystem.Weevaluate whetherGame1promise-breakers’signalsresultedinbenefitsforbothinvestorandtrusteeinGame2,andwhetherthese signals were reliable indicators of subsequent trustee behaviors. Investors in Game 1 promise-breakers were returned $7.28onaverage,whichissignificantlyhigherthantheOUTpayoffof$5(Wilcoxonsignedranktest,p-value=0.05,n=25). Moreover,Game1promise-breakersreturnedsignificantlymoreinGame2thaninGame1(M =$7.28(SD =4.86)versus 1 1 M =$4.60(SD =3.72);Wilcoxonsignedranktest,p-value<0.01,n =n =25).Thisisalsotruewhenwelookatinvestments 2 2 1 2 inthesubsetof23outof28trusteeswhoissuedapologiesandwhereretrusted:theyreturnedsignificantlymoreinthesecond game(M =$7.52(SD =4.81)versusM =$4.61(SD =3.64);Wilcoxonsignedranktest,p-value<0.01,n=23),whichisalso 1 1 2 2 significantlyhigherthantheOUTpayoff(M =$7.52(SD =4.81)versusM =$5;Wilcoxonsignedranktest,p-value=0.03, 1 1 2 n=23). AlthoughinvestmentsinGame2paidoff,westillfindthat60.0%(15/25)ofre-trustedpromise-breakerssubsequently broketheirpromisesagaininGame2–almostirrespectiveoftheapologiesandnewadjustedpromises.Fromspecifications (3)and(4)inTable4,itappearsthatneitherpromisesadjustments,newamountspromised,norapologiesarepredictiveof returninGame2.TheonlyvariablethatpredictsreturninGame2isreturninGame1. 4.2.3. Distrusted Asmentionedabove,16.6%oftrustees(38outof229)werenottrustedinGame1(seeFig.1).Thesourceofthisdistrust appearstobe:(i)thehighervariancearoundtheeven-splitpointofthedistributionofdistrustedpromises(relativetothat ofthedistributionoftrustedpromises;seerightpanelofFig.2),and(ii)alowerdegreeofdefaulttrustfulnessamongGame 1distrustfulinvestor(accountingforthefactthatasizeablenumberofeven-splitpromiseswererejected).Inparticular, inGame1,55.3%(21/38)ofdistrustedtrusteespromisedlessthan$9whileanother10.5%(4/38)ofthempromisedmore than$11.AswithourGame1predictionsoftrustedpromises,weexpectthatpreviouslydistrustedtrusteeswouldadjust theirGame2promisestowardsthemodalandmoretrustedpromiseof$10,thattheseadjustmentswouldaffectdecisions toinvest,andthatinvestmentsmadebasedonadjustedpromiseswouldbenefitboththeinvestorandtrustee. FirstweevaluatewhetherGame1distrustedtrusteesadjusttheirpromisesasweexpected,andifadjustmentsofpromises byGame1distrustedtrusteesaffectinvestmentdecisions.TrusteeswhoweredistrustedinGame1promisedanaverage of$8.92inGame2,whichissimilartotheiraveragepromiseof$8.61inGame1(Wilcoxonsignedranktest,p-value=0.45, n =n =38), yet most investors (84.2% or 32/38) who did not trust in Game 1 chose IN in Game 2. Fig. 5 displays the 1 2 histogramofpromisesmadeinGame2bythe38trusteeswhoweredistrustedinGame1.Distrustedtrusteeschangedtheir distributionofpromisestowardsmoreequalsplits:66.7%(14/21)oftrusteeswhopromisedlessthan$9inGame1increased theirGame2promisesand100%(4/4)oftrusteeswhopromisedmorethan$11inGame1decreasedtheirGame2promises. Correspondingly,amongpreviouslyun-trustinginvestors,92.6%(13/14)ofthosewhoreceivedincreasedpromisesand100% (4/4)ofthosewhoreceivedthedecreasedpromiseschoseINinGame2. IN 84.2% OUT 15.8% 5 5 1 1 0 0 y 1 y1 c c n n e e u u q q e e Fr Fr 5 5 0 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 P romi se P rom ise Fig.5. DistributionofpromisesinGame2(resultinginINorOUT)byGame1distrustedtrustees.
Description: