FALL 2016 • Volume 31 • Number 1 ANTITRUST IN THIS ISSUE MERGERS The Way Forward Direction of Enforcement Litigating the Fix Modifying Consent Decrees Private Equity Cash Tender Offers Competitive Effects Analysis Price Discrimination Markets Using Economist Experts Views from the Bench Quantitative Techniques in EU Discovery Practice: EU vs. U.S. ARTICLES Signaling FTC Consumer Redress Cartel Investigations But-For World Mergers: Understanding the Rules of the Road From the American Bar Association 2015 Annual Review of Antitrust Law Developments Product Code:5030635 Publication Date:2016 Page Count:487 Trim Size:7 x 10 Format:Paper Pricing:1 Copy: $129.00 AT Section Members / $169.00 Regular Price (cid:3)FOR ALMOST 40 YEARS, Antitrust Law related to antitrust injury, standing, Developmentsand its annual supplements have damages, the availability of arbitration, been recognized as the most authoritative and the requirements to maintain a class action, comprehensive set of research tools for the limitations on recovery for foreign antitrust practitioners. The 2015 Annual Review purchases, the standards for injunctive of Antitrust Law Developmentssummarizes relief, motions to dismiss, and motions for developments during 2015 in the courts, summary judgment. at the agencies, and in Congress. ● Antitrust law developments in industry- Among other topics, the 2015 Annual Review specific sectors, including health care, discusses: energy, communications, and transportation. ● Important judicial decisions and government ● International developments in the European enforcement across the major areas of Union, Brazil, Canada, United Kingdom, antitrust law, including agreements in and other jurisdictions. restraint of trade, monopolization, M&A, joint ventures, intellectual property, and Visit our website at www.shopaba.org exemptions and immunities. ● Court rulings on issues central to private antitrust litigation, including developments ANTITRUST • FALL 2016 • VOL. 31 • NO. 1 T A B L E O F C O N T E N T S Mergers: Understanding the Rules of the Road Cover Photo: SuperStock Effective Presentation of Expert Testimony for the C o v e r S t o r i e s Government in a Merger Litigation Editor’s Note by Stephen Mohr and Sophia Vandergrift ....................52 U.S. Merger Enforcement: The Way Forward Economic Testimony in Mergers by Gregory G. Wrobel......................................5 by Timothy F. Bresnahan................................56 Mergers: Litigating the Fix by David Gelfand and Leah O. Brannon.......................10 LITIGATION PRACTICE: NOTES FROM THE FIELD Views from the Bench in Merger Cases Modifying Merger Consent Decrees to Improve by Lisa C. Wood.........................................59 Merger Enforcement Policy by Steven C. Salop .......................................15 INTERNATIONAL MERGER DEVELOPMENTS Private Equity and Antitrust: A New Landscape The Use of Quantitative Economic Techniques in by James A. Keyte and Kenneth B. Schwartz.....................21 EU Merger Control Cash Tender Offers Under the HSR Act: by Thomas Buettner, Giulio Federico, and Szabolcs Lorincz..........68 Protecting an Efficient Market for Corporate Control Convergence and Divergence in the EU and by John D. Harkrider.....................................28 U.S. Approaches to Document Requests in Meet the New “BOSS”: Competitive Effects Analyses Complex Mergers in Staples/Office Depot by Vanessa Turner and Max Kaufman.........................76 by Matthew J. Reilly and Chetan Sanghvi ......................34 Price Discrimination Markets in Merger Cases: A r t i c l e s Practical Guidance from FTC v. Sysco by Ian Simmons, Sergei Zaslavsky, and Lindsey Freeman............40 Sending the Wrong Message? Antitrust Liability for Signaling Using Economist Experts in Merger Litigation: by Paula W. Render, J. Bruce McDonald, and Thomas D. York .......83 Three Essays Time to Stop Digging: Failed Attacks on FTC Authority Four Roles for the Defense Economist in to Obtain Consumer Redress Merger Litigation by David C. Vladeck......................................89 by Daniel M. Wall ....................................49 U.S. Corporate and Individual Cartel Investigations: Navigating the Intersection of Antitrust and A N T I T R U S T White Collar Enforcement ISSN 0162-7996 by Graciela M. Rodriguez, Wendy Huang Waszmer, and Alan R. Dial..96 This magazine is published three times a year (Spring, Summer, and Fall) by the Section of Antitrust Law, American Bar Association, 321 North Clark Street, Chicago, What Is a “But-For World”? IL 60654. The subscription price for members of the Anti trust Section is included in their dues. by Justine S. Hastings and Michael A. Williams .................102 Annual sub scriptions for institutions and individuals not eligible for ABA membership are $75 per year ($85 for Alaska, Hawaii, U.S. Possessions and foreign countries). Single copy price is $30. Please address all subscription mail to Section of Antitrust Law, American Bar D e p a r t m e n t s Association, 321 North Clark Street, Chicago, IL 60654. Nonprofit standard postage paid at Atlanta, GA. Merger Policy and the Debate over the Unsolicited original manuscripts and letters to the editor are welcome and should Direction of Antitrust Enforcement— be sent to Tina Miller, at [email protected]. For more information on our publishing procedures and policies, visit us at www.americanbar.org/publications/antitrust_ Letter from Section Chair William C. MacLeod .............3 magazine_home.html. The views expressed herein are the authors’ only and are not necessarily those of Council Highlights.....................................65 the authors’ firm, the American Bar Association, or the Section of Antitrust Law. Copyright © 2016 American Bar Association F A L L 2 0 1 6 · 1 A N T I T R U S T M A G A Z I N E Executive Editor Editorial Board Chair Tina Miller Gregory G. Wrobel 81 Seventy Acre Rd. Vedder Price PC AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION Redding, CT 06896 222 North LaSalle St. SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW tel 203/938-8507 Chicago, IL 60601 faaxn 2tit0r3us/[email protected] [email protected] CONTINUING LEGAL EDUCATION CALENDAR Articles Editor Articles Editor Litigation Practice Editor Lisa A. Jose Fales Ellen Meriwether Lisa C. Wood Venable LLP Cafferty Clobes Meriwether Foley Hoag LLP 2 0 1 7 – 2 0 1 8 575 7th St., NW & Sprengel LLP 155 Seaport Boulevard Washington, DC 20004 1101 Market St. Boston, MA 02110 Philadelphia, PA 19107 FEBRUARY 2, 2017 Consumer Protection Conference Associate Editors ATLANTA, GA Damian G. Didden Belinda S Lee Sonia K. Pfaffenroth (cid:0) (cid:0) (cid:0) Wachtell Lipton Rosen & Katz Latham & Watkins LLP Washington, DC 51 West 52nd St. 505 Montgomery St. New York, NY 10019 San Francisco, CA 94111 Jeffrey Prisbrey MARCH 29–31, 2017 Charles River Associates 65th Spring Meeting Laila Haider Kellie Lerner 1201 F St., NW Edgeworth Economics LLC Robins Kaplan LLP Washington, DC 20004 WASHINGTON, DC 1225 19th St., NW 601 Lexington Ave. Washington, DC 20036 New York, NY 10022 Michael Schwalbert (cid:0) (cid:0) (cid:0) Missouri Attorney General’s John D. Harkrider Michael A. Lindsay Office MAY 8, 2017 Axinn, Veltrop & Harkrider LLP Dorsey & Whitney LLP 815 Olive Street Global Private Litigation Conference 114 West 47th St. 50 South 6th St. St. Louis, MO 63101 New York, NY 10036 Minneapolis, MN 55402 AMSTERDAM, THE NETHERLANDS Ian Simmons Jeffrey A. Jaeckel Christine S. Meyer O’Melveny & Myers LLP (cid:0) (cid:0) (cid:0) Morrison & Foerster LLP NERA Economic Consulting 1625 Eye St., NW 2000 Pennsylvania Ave., NW 360 Hamilton Ave. Washington, DC 20006 JUNE 1–2, 2017 Washington, DC 20006 White Plains, NY 10601 Antitrust in the Americas Robert A. Skitol Janis Kestenbaum Robin L. Moore Drinker Biddle & Reath LLP MEXICO CITY, MEXICO Perkins Coie LLP Federal Trade Commission 1500 K St., NW 700 13th St., NW 600 Pennsylvania Ave., NW Washington, DC 20005 (cid:0) (cid:0) (cid:0) Washington, DC 20005 Washington, DC 20580 Joshua Soven AUGUST 10–15, 2017 James A. Keyte Andrea Murino Gibson Dunn & Crutcher LLP ABA Annual Meeting Skadden Arps Slate Meagher Goodwin Procter LLP 1050 Connecticut Ave., NW & Flom LLP 901 New York Ave., NW Washington, DC 20036 NEW YORK CITY 4 Times Square Washington, DC 20001 New York, NY 10036 Vanessa A. Turner (cid:0) (cid:0) (cid:0) Jason O’Connor Allen & Overy LLP William J. Kolasky Federal Trade Commission Avenue de Tervueren 268A OCTOBER 2017 Hughes Hubbard & Reed LLP 600 Pennsylvania Ave., NW Brussels 1150 Belgium Antitrust Merger Workshop 1775 I St., NW Washington, DC 20580 Washington, DC 20006 Willard K. Tom WASHINGTON, DC Jack E. Pace III Morgan, Lewis & Bockius LLP James G. Kress White & Case LLP 1111 Pensylvania, Ave., NW (cid:0) (cid:0) (cid:0) Baker Botts LLP 1155 Ave. of the Americas Washington, DC 20004 1299 Pensylvania Ave., NW New York, NY 10036 NOVEMBER 16, 2017 Washington, DC 20004 Fall Forum WASHINGTON, DC Section of Antitrust Law Council Liaison (cid:0) (cid:0) (cid:0) Jonathan I. Gleklen Arnold & Porter LLP FEBRUARY 14–16, 2018 601 Massachusetts Ave., NW Washington, DC 20001 International Cartel Workshop PARIS, FRANCE Design & Production Gary Archambault Archambault Design LLC Please visit http://www.ambar.org/antitrust PO Box 969/552 Torrington Rd.• Litchfield, CT 06759 for detailed conference information. 860/496-0740 [email protected] 2 · A N T I T R U S T D E P A R T M E N T S restrictions on competitors’ conduct, more resources for the F A L L 2 0 1 6 agencies, and a Presidential advisor on antitrust policy. The agencies have weighed in on the debate as well. All from the Section Chair three Commissioners at the FTC and the Assistant Attorney General at the Antitrust Division have given their assess- Merger Policy and the ments of cases brought, cases won, cases lost, and the state of enforcement policy. In speeches available at https://www.ftc. Direction of Antitrust Enforcement Merger policy has preoccupied the debate over the vigor and direction of antitrust enforcement. Skeptics and critics of recent enforcement question whether Dear Colleagues, the agencies have pursued enough deals, whether T HE MAGAZINE THAT the courts have allowed too many, and whether the consistently sets the stan- dard for practical and read- remedies have been effective. able analysis of competition and consumer protection, gov/ and https://www.justice.gov/atr, the agency leaders gave ANTITRUST offers another issue that detailed accounts of the decisions they made on the front blends hot topics and serious scholarship. Here we examine lines of enforcement and the decisions the courts made in rul- the latest developments in merger enforcement and the pol- ing on the challenges. The officials maintain that neither icy informing it, but the contents cover much more ground, aggregate measures of economic concentration nor small from liability for price signaling to redress in consumer pro- samples of individual transactions can diagnose the compet- tection cases, to new criminal exposure for cartel defendants. itive effects that the agencies examine in extensive investiga- As always, the articles include healthy helpings of economics. tions. They note that economists have discounted the pre- This issue could not have come at a better time. Merger sumption pitting concentration against competition. policy has preoccupied the debate over the vigor and direc- All of these perspectives illuminate important aspects of tion of antitrust enforcement. Skeptics and critics of recent economic policy and the role of merger policy. How do we enforcement question whether the agencies have pursued square the critics’ reviews with the officials’ reports? enough deals, whether the courts have allowed too many, and Let’s hear from the witnesses. We don’t yet have the per- whether the remedies have been effective. spectives of the practitioners and experts who stepped into In an Issue Brief last April (https://www.whitehouse.gov/), the courtrooms to present the evidence, articulate the theo- the Council of Economic Advisors listed 13 industry cate- ries, and argue the law that governs the outcomes. And we gories and observed that the shares of the top 50 firms in 10 haven’t heard from the judges who determined the outcomes of them had increased in the last 15 years. The categories were (although their opinions portend where they might come out so broad that the top 50 firms accounted for less than half the in the debate). This issue of ANTITRUST rounds out the revenue in all but one—utilities. But increases of up to11 record. In the following pages, those who litigated and ruled percentage points inspired CEA to suggest that “record lev- on the cases give their accounts. Competition and consumers, els” of M&A had left behind “more market concentration, not to mention practitioners and commentators, will bene- higher profits for a few firms, and declining entry, all of fit from the knowledge that these articles impart. which could result from less competition.” After acknowl- For more on mergers, the October issue of The Antitrust edging the enforcement efforts of the agencies, CEA con- Sourceoffers tips on handling nonparty witnesses in merger cluded, “There may however be scope for additional actions litigation, and a Roundtable discussion of substantive and to be taken . . . .” procedural issues facing merger practitioners today, as well as Delving more deeply into transactional data, the Center coverage of late-breaking topics we have come to expect from for American Progress reviewed academic studies of selected our online authors at The Source.(cid:3) mergers and concluded that decades of inadequate antitrust enforcement has allowed companies to acquire market power With best regards, and raise prices. Its report, “Reviving Antitrust” (https://www. americanprogress.org/), cited research that purported to find price increases after the agencies allowed mergers to proceed, William C. MacLeod and called for stronger presumptions of illegality in horizon- Chair, ABA Section of Antitrust Law tal mergers, increased scrutiny of vertical deals, tougher 2016–2017 F A L L 2 0 1 6 · 3 NEW from the American Bar Association TO: Antitrust Section Members Consumer Protection Law FROM: Wiiliam C. MacLeod, Chair, Section of Antitrust Law Developments Second Edition SUBJECT: Nominating Committee (cid:3)PURSUANT TO THE BYLAWSof the Section of Antitrust Product Code:5030634 Law, the Chair of the Section is called upon to appoint a Publication Date:2016 Nominating Committee composed of five Section members Page Count:1400 to make nominations to the Section membership for open Trim Size:7 x 10 Format:Hardbound positions among the Officers and Council to be elected at the next Annual Meeting. I am pleased to announce that Pricing: $475.00 List Price / I have appointed the following distinguished members of $399.00 AT Section Member the Section to serve on the 2016–2017 Nominating Committee: (cid:3)THE ABA SECTION Howard Feller, Chair OF ANTITRUST LAW McGuire Woods LLP continues its longstanding tradition of scholarship and service for Gateway Plaza the practitioner with this Second Edition of Consumer Protection 800 East Canal Street Law Developm ents(CPLD). Consumer protection laws seek to Richmond, VA 23219-3916 correct a misimpression that a product or service has a greater [email protected] value than it actually does and, by doing so, prevent consumer injury. Understanding this objective, however, is a good deal Willam L. Greene Stinson Leonard Street easier than under standing the many federal and state laws 150 South 5th Street • Suite 2300 designed to accomplish it. Minneapolis, MN 55402-4238 Since its first edition in 2009, the mission of CPLDhas been to [email protected] synthesize consumer protection law into a coherent and objective summary of court decisions, enforcement actions, agency Jeffrey A. LeVee regulations, and guidelines, in an important and evolving area Jones Day of law. CPLDprovides information on administrative litigation, 555 South Flower Street • Floor 50 consumer class actions, Lanham Act and Sherman Act litigation, Los Angeles, CA 90071-2300 and express, implied, and establishment claims; qualitative and [email protected] quantitative consumer perception analysis; industry standard, modified industry standards, and non-standard product testing; M. Howard Morse Cooley LLP statistical analysis and more. 1299 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW • Suite 700 This second edition also covers significant consumer Washington, DC 20004-2400 |protection developments since the last hardbound publication, [email protected] including the addition of a separate chapter on the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB), as well as significant Christine J. Sommer discussions about the impact of new technologies on consumer WilmerHale protection law, the expansion in state consumer protection law 1875 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW enforcement, and ever growing importance of international Washington, DC 20006-3642 legal precedent. Consumer Protection Law Developmentsis a [email protected] comprehensive and up-to-date analysis of this important and complex subject and the perfect companion treatise to Antitrust Any member of the Section wishing to make recommendations to the Nominating Committee Law Developments. should convey comments to the Nominating Committee Chair or to any other member of the Committee. Visit our website at www.shopaba.org 4 · A N T I T R U S T Editor’s Note: attention than might be anticipated from the small number of litigated merger cases. Mergers and the court cases they draw are often highly visible and fast paced; media sources, U.S. Merger analysts, and legislators often depict these deals as flash points for debate on wider issues of economic, fiscal, trade, and even social and political policy; and the record of the agen- Enforcement: cies in merger cases is often used as a litmus test for their over- all effectiveness as antitrust enforcers. The Way Forward As this issue of ANTITRUST was proceeding to publica- tion, Acting Assistant Attorney General Renata Hesse and FTC Chairwoman Edith Ramirez gave speeches and The Economisthad a cover theme that touched in important ways BY GREGORY G. WROBEL on the public face of mergers and merger enforcement.2Key passages from the speeches serve well to illustrate issues that animate current public discourse on the process and focus of U.S. merger enforcement. T HE COVER THEME OF THIS FALL Enforcement Goals: Fairness, Transparency, 2016 issue of ANTITRUST focuses on U.S. Technical Analysis merger enforcement, with articles offering prac- Hesse focused on public perceptions of economic fairness, tical and forward-looking guidance for antitrust and using court cases to make the technical analysis of attorneys, economists, courts, and in-house antitrust enforcement more accessible, while Ramirez focused counsel who must decode antitrust law for their business on safeguarding the competitive process without seeking to managers. This column affords some leeway for broader com- reshape markets to achieve broader policy goals. ments on the focus of U.S. merger enforcement, which has been shaped in large part by legal standards and economic Hesse principles adopted by courts over many years under Section At bottom, these diverse voices agree on the basic proposition 7 of the Clayton Act, rather than by economic, fiscal, and that it is unfair to allow companies to grab unearned monop- trade policy goals that a new administration may pursue. oly power over markets that they can wield at the expense of For the most part, modern U.S. merger enforcement consumers, workers, and would-be competitors. By and encompasses: (1) compliance with premerger notification large, I think this increased public interest in antitrust and requirements for larger deals; (2) focused investigations in a competition is a good thing. It is good for the public— small percentage of deals by the Department of Justice Anti - because antitrust enforcement promotes the interests of the trust Division and Federal Trade Commission (in some cases public over the power of the few—and it is also good for with participation by state attorneys general); the (3) negoti- antitrust—because it keeps enforcers focused on the ulti- mate goal of antitrust, economic fairness. ated settlements (mostly structural relief; some behavioral/ conduct remedies) in a small fraction of deals with premerg- * * * * * er filings (plus a few non-reported transactions); and (4) con- Animating the beliefs of ordinary Americans who demand tested court cases (and/or FTC administrative cases), for a very vigorous antitrust enforcement are the value of fairness and small percentage of challenged deals that are not settled.1 the belief that properly functioning competitive markets are Private plaintiffs may have standing to pursue claims under themselves fair. To say it another way, competition is fair because it gives a chance to the small business owner to suc- Section 7 of the Clayton Act, but these claims are infrequent ceed in her business venture, because it delivers lower prices and rarely prevent deals from closing. to consumers, and because it drives the innovation that The articles in this theme are part of extensive ongoing improves products, business processes, and more. coverage of merger enforcement by ANTITRUST. This level of attention is warranted both for analytical reasons that * * * * * It is our job as public servants to explain to the public why antitrust practitioners can appreciate (e.g., merger cases pres- we do what we do; for example, when we use economics tools ent unique challenges in both factual and economic analysis), with obscure names like “Herfindahl-Hirschman Index” or and because merger enforcement attracts broader public “Gross Upward Pricing Pressure Index,” we are simply meas- uring intuitive phenomena like the concentration of eco- nomic power or the tendency of mergers to reduce compet- Gregory G. Wrobel, Editorial Board Chair of ANTITRUST, is a shareholder and itive pressures that keep prices down. . . . I believe strongly head of the Antitrust Practice Group of Vedder Price P.C. All opinions that in the last decade we have been reducing the gap expressed herein are his alone and do not necessarily reflect those of his between expert and popular antitrust as we have been liti- firm or any of its clients. gating more and more cases, forcing us to explain our claims F A L L 2 0 1 6 · 5 E D I T O R ’ S N O T E of harmed competition to lay judges and juries who must Ramirez determine the rightness of our causes. Antitrust is too impor- The Council of Economic Advisors, for example, cites tant to be left solely in the hands of antitrust experts. increases in corporate profits and revenue share of the 50 leading firms in various industries, as well [as] downward Ramirez trends in firm entry and exit rates to suggest there may be rea- We are not in the business of picking winners or losers; our son for concern about the current state of competition. The job is to enforce the rules that safeguard vigorous competi- Economistsimilarly identifies high profits, particularly in cer- tion if we see them being broken. We prefer to leave markets tain sectors like technology and health care, as a basis for con- alone, allowing customer preferences to dictate what will be cluding that the U.S. economy must be “too cozy for incum- produced and sold, and competition to determine which bents,” while the Wall Street Journal attributes lessened firms make what goods and at what price. Competition leads innovation and weak start-up activity to supposed market to lower prices, higher quality, and innovation, all to the concentration. benefit of consumers. * * * * * * * * * * But, in contrast to the granular assessment of individual [O]ur role is by necessity a limited one. First and foremost, markets that we undertake when evaluating the competitive we are law enforcers, not sector regulators. Our job is not to effects of increases in concentration, broad industry measures transform markets; we must take them as they are. We also like those cited by the CEA, The Economist, and the Wall Street Journaltell us little about market dynamics or the level have no direct authority over prices. High prices unaccom- of competition in a particular industry. The fact that there panied by anticompetitive behavior do not violate the may be fewer firms today in certain sectors than in years past antitrust laws. Without more, neither do price increases does not necessarily mean that these sectors are any less com- resulting from inadequate supply or other natural market dis- petitive from a consumer welfare perspective. ruptions. We act only when the competitive process itself is harmed or threatened, through anticompetitive combina- * * * * * tions or conduct. Nor can we simply decry an increase in the presence of large firms—or even dominant ones—merely because they are Second, we intervene only when the facts warrant it. This big or have a high market share, although deals and conduct requires a deep analytical dive into reliable qualitative and involving such firms are more likely to draw antitrust scruti- quantitative evidence to understand the actual or likely com- ny. In many cases, being big is a consequence of being bet- petitive impact of the merger or conduct under scrutiny. ter than rivals at offering customers what they want. We are rightly hesitant to view success, and by extension size, with Size and Concentration automatic suspicion. Indeed, large firms can have scale Hesse and Ramirez expressed similar views that growth of economies and other efficiencies that are beneficial for con- large firms and economy-wide trends toward consolidation sumers. In short, one cannot assess the state of competition are not proper targets for antitrust/merger enforcement. in the absence of a fact-intensive analysis of specific product and service overlaps, the availability of substitutes, and other Hesse relevant market dynamics. The big-is-bad view takes aim, as I see it, at the wrong tar- get for antitrust enforcers. First of all, many of the measures Consumer Welfare, Competitive Impact, and of concentration have from an antitrust perspective the Presumption of Anticompetitive Effects wrong measure of bigness in mind. Antitrust is concerned Hesse and Ramirez both reference the presumption of anti- with a situation where a firm or firms are large enough in competitive effects for merged firms with a high market share proportion to the rest of the market—and thus face too lit- in concentrated markets. Hesse goes a bit further in arguing tle competition—that they can raise prices alone or take that effects on competition and the competitive process, actions that prevent new competition from undercutting rather than impact on consumer welfare, are the guiding high prices. Such firms, we say, have “market power.” Many standard for enforcement action. concentration studies simply do not measure market power in this way. Hesse * * * * * Second, even when we have the right measure of bigness in Just as some popular views of antitrust miss the mark some- mind—that is, market power—market power by itself is not what, so do some of the expert views . . . Some commenta- the focus of antitrust . . . . In other words, antitrust enforcers tors have accordingly suggested that the antitrust laws should don’t go after firms that become large just because they are judge all practices by their impact on the welfare of down- good at competing. So long as competitive processes are not stream consumers, as measured by price and output effects subverted, new firms can rise to displace today’s winners. in downstream markets. But, although we believe competi- That is how competition works. We are concerned with sit- tion maximizes consumer welfare, the ultimate standard by uations where market power is achieved or protected by anti- which we judge practices is their effect on competition, not competitive means. on consumer welfare. 6 · A N T I T R U S T * * * * * One bedrock tool for protecting against anticompetitive mergers has been recognized by the Supreme Court for over fifty years. In Philadelphia National Bank, decided in1963, the Supreme Court announced that “a merger which pro- duces a firm controlling an undue percentage share of the rel- evant market, and results in a significant increase in the con- centration of firms in that market is so inherently likely to lessen competition substantially” that the law will presume it unlawful. * * * * * That said, in the more routine horizontal merger case we almost always do introduce proof of consumer harm where it exists—along with demonstrating likely reductions in qual- ity and slowing of innovation—because we want to present Stock aply r faoucnltli ctahecsec topour entshtue mo ffip nttdhioeern a:o nfe tvfiaecncotm .w Mpheeotrirete iopvevr iecere,f f waecnet dsr aooruef ltycph uraetll lyee fnsfoegcleetd-s Photo: Super cannot be quantified, we usually have some concrete evidence such as documents or lay testimony showing that competi- disputes. When cases are settled, the conversation hardly tion between the merging firms is important and will be lost leaves the corridors of agencies and law firms, and so it can with a merger. stay at the rarified level of economics tools such as HHIs, cross-price elasticities, and GUPPIs. When we litigate, we put Ramirez our dispute before a neutral lay arbiter—a judge or a jury. That means we have to tell a compelling and coherent story For us, of course, stopping anticompetitive combinations is about why certain business practices are harming competi- among the most important jobs we perform. And market tion and thereby participants in the economy. The proof shares and market structure continue to play an important will be varied, and it will almost always include sophisticat- role in merger analysis and enforcement, even as our focus ed expert presentation of economics evidence—theoretical or has shifted to more direct assessments of competitive effects. empirical or both—as part of the evidence. But that must be Where a proposed merger significantly increases concentra- packaged with qualitative evidence that confirms in a palpa- tion in an already highly concentrated market, we are justi- ble and intuitive way the story told through the numbers of fiably entitled to a presumption of competitive harm. the expert. And ultimately the plaintiff’s story should high- light the moral underpinnings of the antitrust laws—fight- Trials and Settlements ing against the unfairness of concentrated economic power Hesse and Ramirez both emphasize litigation readiness as an profiting at the expense of consumers, suppliers, or com- effective tool to achieve enforcement goals. Hesse also argues petitors who could challenge the defendant’s dominance. that public trials shift how cases are prepared and presented. Hesse Ramirez As a matter of process, the way that antitrust as expert prac- To those who think us too permissive, I note that the Com - tice has become more engaged with the general public’s mission has challenged 44 mergers in the last two years alone, enthusiasm for antitrust, and to make itself more relevant to including suing to stop eight transactions outright. Among the public, is to change the way disputes are resolved. We other major wins, we successfully challenged the Sysco/US have been moving from a quasi-regulatory system—in which Foods, Staples/Office Depot, and St. Luke’s/Saltzer mergers. disputes are typically resolved by settlement crafted largely We have been particularly active in addressing what we within the halls of the agencies—to a litigation mode— believe to be anticompetitive consolidation in the healthcare, where disputes are more often resolved by lay third-party pharmaceutical, retail, and energy sectors, among others. arbiters. * * * * * * * * * * . . . [M]ost often we are able to resolve the competition con- Showing to the public that we are prepared to litigate has cerns we identify through consent orders requiring divesti- paid off: in this administration, a total of 40 mergers have tures of overlapping products. Settlements offer the advan- been blocked by court order or wholly abandoned by the tage of addressing the competitive harm of a transaction merging companies in the face of our investigation, a stark while still allowing realization of the merger’s efficiencies. increase from 16 in the prior administration. Despite their many advantages, however, our remedies have also been the subject of criticism. * * * * * Litigating more means changing the way we talk about our * * * * * F A L L 2 0 1 6 · 7 E D I T O R ’ S N O T E Some contend that the FTC would rather accept an inade- market movements for public companies). This means that quate remedy rather than litigate. Our recent track record, the cases are presented in court through preliminary injunc- including our merger suits in Sysco/US Foods, Staples/Office tion proceedings or their functional equivalent, with highly Depot, and Superior/Canexus, directly belie that contention. compressed discovery and expert work. In each of these cases, the parties offered substantial divesti- These dynamics may not produce the best factual records tures to buyers ready to compete in the business, but we for district court decisions, given the inherent complexities of determined that the divestitures would not fully replicate the expert analysis and the use of historical information to pre- competition lost through the merger and appropriately dict future market events. Decisions of the district courts rejected them. typically stand as the last word in merger cases due to time pressures that the parties face but the agencies do not, which The Way Forward may leave the agencies better positioned to exercise rights of This publication is not usually a forum for high-level debate appeal if they lose in the district court.3 on antitrust policy, and certainly not on broader govern- Public commentary on antitrust and competition policy ment policy toward large and growing firms across the full has been more visible recently than is typical for election spectrum of regulation, taxation, equality in compensation, cycles. Ramirez notes that “[w]ith election day fast approach- or other concerns. Rather, we focus on how antitrust practi- ing, we find ourselves in the midst of a public debate over tioners, courts, and parties in cases grapple with issues (and the effectiveness of current competition policy in the United merger deals) under existing law. States,” and both Hesse and The Economist invoke populist The same is and should be true for agency merger enforce- sentiments of economic fairness, opportunities for small ment. Substantive standards under Section 7 focus on com- businesses to compete, employment impact, and backlash petition in the relevant market(s) directly affected by a merg- against “corporatism” (presumably an undesirable relation- er, not broader economic or social consequences of the deal ship between large companies and government).4 These or its effects on wider trends in the U.S. economy (or glob- themes seem to be resonating now across a range of policy ally) in firm size, employment, wage levels, or myriad other issues that are much more pressing for voters than govern- factors. ment merger enforcement. But the economic trends that Enforcement agencies exercise discretion over what deals prompt these sentiments cannot be laid at the doorstep of to investigate and challenge, but they do not possess (or exer- mergers, as many large firms have grown their core business- cise, in the case of the FTC) authority to issue regulations es internally. Nor should these sentiments shape the legal pronouncing new substantive antitrust standards to animate standards under Section 7 that courts now apply in merger Section 7.That job is left to U.S. courts. It is noteworthy that cases, and that presumably guide enforcement decisions (and Hesse prominently cited the Philadelphia National Bank agency enforcement guidelines). Supreme Court decision dating back to 1963 for the pre- Hesse describes a deliberate shift from technical analysis of sumed correlation between market concentration and com- consumer welfare leading to negotiated settlements, in favor petitive harm. Courts can make new law under Section 7 of merger cases tried to district court judges, focused more only when ruling on litigated merger cases, and the Supreme broadly on effects on competition and the competitive Court and federal courts of appeals seldom receive (or accept) process. But her comments are balanced with the continuing merger cases to review. need to delve into technical details of economic analysis, Both Hesse and Ramirez note that litigation readiness matched with evidence from the merger parties and other helps to achieve enforcement goals, and Hesse argues that the market participants. increasing number of cases going to trial serves broader goals Merger cases are inherently forward-looking, predicting in publicly communicating the moral underpinnings of likely competitive impacts that often require a range of ana- antitrust law. More frequent litigation of merger cases may lytical tools and expert evidence that are grounded in vary- produce fresh judicial guidance on substantive standards and ing ways in economic theory and methods. A shift to trials in proof required to block mergers. The goal of merger enforce- court will not change the use of these tools or the complex- ment, however, is not to create new case law, but rather to ity of the evidence they produce, as the economic theory step in only where deals that emerge from the broth of glob- and models from which these tools derive are now deeply al competition pose a direct threat to competition and con- embedded in antitrust standards.5 sumer welfare in particular relevant markets in which the Mechanisms already exist to promote greater public aware- merger parties overlap. ness of merger cases that are not litigated. The agencies issue Important traits of merger deals, by their nature, create statements that explain proposed settlements in merger cases challenges that impede the evolution of case law under to aid in public comment before final action on the settle- Section 7. For the most part, merger cases must be tried ment. Perhaps more can be done in individual cases (and under the time pressures of the HSR review process and ter- periodically on a collective basis) to explain the technical mination dates embedded in the parties’ agreements and analysis used in both litigated merger cases and settlements, financing arrangements (in addition to the forces of stock and thereby bridge the divide noted by Hesse between 8 · A N T I T R U S T
Description: