ebook img

A Critique of Soviet Economics PDF

157 Pages·1977·4.853 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview A Critique of Soviet Economics

A Critique of Soviet Economics A Critique of Soviet Econom ics by Mao Tsetung Translated by Moss Roberts Annotated by Richard Levy With an Introduction by James Pech Monthly Review Press New York and London Copyright © 1977 by Moss Roberts All rights reserved Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Mao, Tsetung, 1893-1976. A critique of Soviet economics. CONTENTS: Reading notes on the Soviet text Political Economy.—Concerning Economic Problems of Socialism in the Soviet Union.—Critique of Stalin’s Economic Problems of Socialism in the Soviet Union. 1. Economics—Russia 2. Akademiia nauk SSSR. Institut ékonomiki. Politicheskaia ékonomiia 3. Stalin, Iosif, 1879-1953. Ékonomicheskie problemy sotsializma v SSSR. 4. Russia—Economic policy— 1917- 5. China—Economic policy. I. Title. HB113.A2M34213 330\0947 77-70971 ISBN 0-85345-412-4 Monthly Review Press 62 West 14th Street, New York, N.Y. 10011 47 Red Lion Street, London WC1R 4PF Manufactured in the United States of America 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Contents Introduction 7 Notes on the Texts 30 Reading Notes on the Soviet Text Political Economy 33 Concerning Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR 129 Critique of Stalin’s Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR 135 Notes 149 Introduction These writings of Mao Tsetung, brought together here under the tide A Critique of Soviet Economics, date from the period during and immediately after the Great Leap Forward, a time when the Chinese Revolution began to break decisively with the Soviet Union and its model of development. With the Great Leap, a distinctive Chinese road to socialism emerged. But it was a road paved with a decade of controversy over the course of China’s socialist development. At the heart of many of those disputes within the Chinese Communist Party was the question of the applicability of the Russian experience to building socialism in China. In analyzing their own society, the Chinese Communists have long studied the Russian Revolution for inspiration and practical suggestions, as well as for a general perspective on the course of their own revolution. To them, the Soviet Union is a model from which both negative and positive lessons can be drawn. Thus it is not surprising to find Mao, at such a pivotal stage in the Chinese Revolution as the Great Leap, once again turning to a study of Soviet experience. This time he did so through a critique of two Soviet books, Political Economy: A Textbook and Joseph Stalin’s Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR. By the time Mao wrote his critique, however, he had moved away from trying to adapt Soviet methods, as he and other party leaders had sought to do in the early 1950s, and instead began to advocate strongly a wide range of alternatives. 7 8 Introduction A Critique of Soviet Economics can usefully be read from several, closely interwoven perspectives: (1) as a crucial ini­ tial summing up by Mao of what the Soviet model was and what it implied for China; (2) as a strong defense of the Great Leap Forward from the perspective of uninterrupted revolu­ tion; (3) as a pathbreaking examination of the principles of Soviet political economy and of several key aspects of the Russian revolutionary experience, particularly the years under Stalin’s leadership. The texts translated in this volume include a critique of the Soviet work, Political Economy: A Textbook, along with a supplement Mao wrote to his own critique, a talk on Stalin’s Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR, and a critique of the Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR. Mao’s consideration of Stalin’s Economic Problems together with the Russian political economy text is quite appropriate, as Stalin’s work was itself written as a series of comments for the draft textbook on political economy, which was finished and released only after his death. This Russian text in its various Russian/Chinese editions circulated in China from the mid-1950s on. After the Lushan Conference in 1959, Mao called upon party members to critically study the third edition. This was the edition upon which his critique is based. THE SOVIET MODEL______________________ Throughout most of the history of the Chinese Communist Party, controversy over how to deal with the experience of the Russian Revolution has been at the heart of what the Chinese call the “two-line struggle.” From its founding in 1921, conflicts within the party have in one way or another been linked to individuals who favored the orthodox Russian conception of revolution. The defeat of Li Li-san in the 1930s, Wang Ming in the 1940s, Kao Kang (Gau Gang) and P’eng Teh-huai (Peng Deh-huai) in the 1950s, and Liu Shao-ch’i (Liu Shau-qi) in the 1960s have all entailed con­ Introduction 9 troversies over the nature and applicability of the Soviet model. Until 1949, these disputes in China focused on the appro­ priate strategy and tactics of the revolutionary struggle for power, the nature of the mass line, and the correct way to apply Marxism-Leninism to the concrete conditions of China. Stalin only reluctantly tolerated the methods and innovations associated with Mao and his followers, especially as they were worked out during the years in Yenan (1937-1945). In the 1940s, he even opposed the successful struggle for libera­ tion. “The Chinese revolution won victory,” Mao later said, “by acting contrary to Stalin’s will. . . . If we had followed Wang Ming’s, or in other words, Stalin’s, method the Chinese revolution couldn’t have succeeded.”1 With Liberation, however, the Chinese saw the Soviet Union as the model for socialist development. Mao had warned his colleagues in 1949 that “our past work is only the first step in a long march of 10,000 li”—“a brief prologue to a long drama.”2 Yet in these early days, there was no model of socialist development other than the Russian, with its reli­ ance on elite-planned and bureaucratically administered pro­ grams of economic development which unduly subordinate the needs of the countryside to the demands of heavy indus­ try. The Soviet Union, despite all, was a society which had achieved industrialization and collectivization, key goals of all the leaders of the Chinese Communist Party. The Soviet vic­ tory over fascism in the Second World War was to many Chinese leaders proof of the success of that society. And at a time of intense American government hostility, a U.S.- backed blockade and bombings of its coast, and later a world­ wide economic embargo, it was quite natural that China leaned toward the Soviet Union in its defense and economic policies. “In the early stages of Liberation,” Mao writes in this vol­ ume, “we had no experience of managing the economy of the entire nation. So in the period of the first five-year plan we could do no more than copy the Soviet Union’s methods, al­ though we never felt altogether satisfied about it.”3 This 10 Introduction growing dissatisfaction focused around three main aspects of the Soviet model: (1) “primitive socialist accumulation”4 at the expense of the peasantry; (2) a theory of productive forces and the dictatorship of the proletariat; (3) a conception of the Communist Party in China. Primitive Socialist Accumulation at the Expense of the Peasantry A Chinese slogan of the early 1950s, “the Soviet Union today is our tomorrow,” captures the spirit with which many Chi­ nese undertook to copy Soviet methods. China’s first five-year plan was notable for its almost exclusive reliance on heavy industry; highly centralized, bureaucratic methods of planning; and little emphasis on light industry and the production of consumer goods. The peasantry was considered largely as a source of savings. Powerful, centralized economic ministries were established in Peking. They introduced rigid hierarchi­ cal systems of control and “one-man management” in the factories, and relied on highly paid specialists alone to direct them. To stimulate productive activity and monitor enteiprise performance, material incentives were widely promoted. The Soviet Union actively encouraged such develop­ ments. And China’s relations with the socialist world after 1949 quite naturally entailed giving a priority to those areas where cooperation was easiest and most meaningful: heavy industry, an educational system designed to train profession­ als and technicians to administer the Soviet-style five-year plan; the spread of professionalization in the armed forces. Indeed, what was happening in the People’s Liberation Army symbolizes what was happening throughout the urban areas of China. With the adoption in February 1955 of the “Regulations on the Service of Officers,” the Chinese officer corps acquired the trappings of a regular army. And in in­ troducing a system of ranks, tides, and widely divergent pay scales for officers and enlisted personnel, the PLA was turn­ ing its back on the informal, egalitarian, and democratic character which had been molded in years of revolutionary warfare.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.