ebook img

The Self-Perception of Early Modern Capitalists PDF

280 Pages·2008·2.225 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The Self-Perception of Early Modern Capitalists

The Self-Perception of Early Modern Capitalists Margaret C. Jacob and Catherine Secretan Palgrave macmillan the self-perception of early modern capitalists Copyright © Margaret C. Jacob and Catherine Secretan, 2008. Softcover reprint of the hardcover 1st edition 2008 978-0-230-60447-6 All rights reserved. First published in 2008 by PALGRAVE MACMILLAN® in the US - a division of St. Martin’s Press LLC, 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, NY 10010. Where this book is distributed in the UK, Europe and the rest of the world, this is by Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited, registered in England, company number 785998, of Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS. Palgrave Macmillan is the global academic imprint of the above companies and has companies and representatives throughout the world. Palgrave® and Macmillan® are registered trademarks in the United States, the United Kingdom, Europe and other countries. ISBN 978-0-230-61781-0 ISBN 978-0-230-61380-5 (eBook) DOI 10.1007/978-0-230-61380-5 Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data The self-perception of early modern capitalists / edited by Margaret C. Jacob and Catherine Secretan. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. 1. Merchants—History. 2. Commerce—History. I. Jacob, Margaret C., 1943- II. Secretan, Catherine. HF479.S45 2008 381.09—dc22 2007052833 A catalogue record of the book is available from the British Library. Design by Scribe Inc. First edition: August 2008 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Transferred to Digital Printing 2008 Contents List of Illustrations v Acknowledgments vii Introduction 1 Margaret C. Jacob (University of California at Los Angeles) and Catherine Secretan (Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique) Part I Prologue 1 Theological Roots of the Medieval/Modern Merchants’ 17 Self-Representation Giacomo Todeschini (University of Trieste) Part II Self-Images 2 Images and Self-Images of Sephardic Merchants in Early 49 Modern Europe and the Mediterranean Francesca Trivellato (Yale University) 3 Merchants in Charge: The Self-Perception of Amsterdam 75 Merchants, ca. 1550–1700 Clé Lesger (University of Amsterdam) 4 Merchants on the Defensive: National Self-Images in the 99 Dutch Republic of the Late Eighteenth Century Dorothee Sturkenboom (Roosevelt Academy Middelburg, Utrecht University) Part III Capitalism as Normative 5 “Merchants” and “Gentlemen” in Eighteenth-Century 125 Sweden: Worlds of Jean Abraham Grill Leos Müller (Uppsala University) iv Contents 6 Professional Ethics and Commercial Rationality at the 147 Beginning of the Modern Era Jochen Hoock (University of Paris, Paris 7-Denis Diderot) 7 The Anxious Merchant, the Bold Speculator, and the 161 Malicious Bankrupt: Doing Business in Eighteenth-Century Hamburg Mary Lindemann (University of Miami) 8 Accounting for War and Revolution: Philadelphia 183 Merchants and Commercial Risk, 1774–1811 Cathy Matson (University of Delaware) Part IV Individuals and Striving 9 Accounting for Science: How a Merchant Kept His 205 Books in Elizabethan London Deborah E. Harkness (University of Southern California) 10 Coming of Age in Trade: Masculinity and Commerce in 229 Eighteenth-Century England John Smail (University of North Carolina, Charlotte) 11 Success and Self-Loathing in the Life of an 253 Eighteenth-Century Entrepreneur Matthew Kadane (Hobart and William Smith Colleges) Index 273 Illustrations 2.1 Ottoman Jewish Merchant in Istanbul 61 2.2 The Dedication of the Portuguese Jewish Synagogue 64 in Amsterdam 3.1 Amsterdam’s City Maiden (Amsterdamse Stedemaagd, 86 by Reinier Vinkeles 1741–1816) 4.1 First economic print. Atlas van Stolk, Engelsche kraam 101 etc., no. 4318, Stichting Atlas van Stolk, Rotterdam. 4.2 The World of the Great. Detail from Atlas van Stolk, 102 Engelsche kraam etc., no. 4318, Stichting Atlas van Stolk, Rotterdam. 4.3 Klaas as would-be gentleman. Detail from Atlas van 103 Stolk, Engelsche kraam etc., no. 4318, Stichting Atlas van Stolk, Rotterdam. 4.4 Second economic print. Atlas van Stolk, Eerwaardigen 104 Nederlander, no. 4322, Stichting Atlas van Stolk, Rotterdam. 4.5 Patriotic citizens following Reason. Detail from Atlas 105 van Stolk, Eerwaardigen Nederlander, no. 4322, Stichting Atlas van Stolk, Rotterdam. 6.1 European production of commercial texts in the 150 sixteenth century 7.1 John Parish (1743–1829) 169 Acknowledgments The editors wish to thank the Center for Seventeenth and Eigh- teenth Centuries Studies at UCLA and its director, Peter Reill, who made possible the conference out of which these essays emerged. Our authors have been especially diligent about the timetable we set for producing their final texts, and for that we are also very grateful. Funding for this project came from both the CNRS, and UCLA and its then dean, Scott Waugh. Finally, the editors would like to acknowl- edge their mutual enjoyment and enrichment from this rewarding international collaboration. 4 Introduction Margaret C. Jacob, University of California at Los Angeles and Catherine Secretan, Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique S ince antiquity, the handling of money and the urge to profit have generally been regarded with suspicion. Within cultures that had for so long juxtaposed material wealth to spiritual possessions only to find the first of far less merit, earthly pursuits were suspected of being inspired by greed, and merchants were seen as acting solely in their own interest. In fostering mistrust toward mercantile activity, Aris- totle’s Politics, Holy Writ, and the patristic tradition (St. Ambrose, St. Jerome) contributed greatly. Their common prohibition of usury, combined with the value that the Church attached to poverty as the Christian perfection, gave little meaning to the pursuit of riches. But there were also social stigmas associated with republican ideol- ogy, views that identified the “capitalist” as a “monster of fortune, a man with a heart of brass, and who has only metallic affection.”1 He is an architect of social inequality. How then did people who sought to make profit—striving to acquire and expand their money— view themselves? If the social utility of the mercatores never ceased 2 Introduction to be asserted from medieval theology to eighteenth-century phi- losophy, protecting one’s reputation remained a chief preoccupation among merchants. Self-perception deserves special attention in the case of early mod- ern “capitalists”—a term only introduced in the eighteenth century— because it concerns individuals coping with a problematical moral identity who are also living on the cusp of a fundamental transfor- mation in the nature of the European economy. For the most part they are living before the triumph of homo economicus: seen as selfish, materialistic, and always imagined in modern and classical economic theory as governed by self-interest. Perhaps early modern merchants are better understood by recourse to more recent models of the eco- nomic actor. They postulate a human disposition to cooperate with others and to punish those who fail to promote that societal goal, i.e., normative constraints like self-discipline, politeness, and respectability play important roles in economic behavior.2 If that more recent model of economic actors seeks validation, its advocates need only take a close look at the chapters before us. The wide range of cases and contexts analyzed in these chapters offer a unique chance to place the question of moral identity in a compara- tive historical perspective. Topics as complex as “self perceptions”— even definitions of capitalism—can be more reliably addressed when seen from that wider perspective. At the same time, although no archetype of a merchant exists, a closer examination of each case study reveals how similarities in mentality, behavior, and self-images recur. The chapters ahead attempt to understand how early capitalists under- stood themselves, and each author seeks to locate similarities as well as differences. Whether we are looking at Catholic or Protestant or Jewish merchants—in Elizabethan London or eighteenth-century Amsterdam or Hamburg—we see certain patterns. Struggling with the vagaries of the market raised moral or ethical issues. All required thought and elicited emotions from fear to self-congratulation. From the medieval theologians who learnedly addressed worldly interests to a mid-eighteenth-century Leeds merchant who literally agonized about the threat posed to his salvation by his worldliness, the market fascinated and elicited thought and feeling. Living within the framework of commercial capitalism—and even- tually, by the early nineteenth century, within the ethos of industrial capitalism—was not the same thing as living with money. Money is not capital. It becomes capital when it is used to make more money, i.e., profit. Wages are not capital, but they can become capital if saved for the purpose of ventures or enterprises intended to make capital.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.