NORTH CAROLINA JOURNAL OF LAW & TECHNOLOGY Volume 5 Article 4 Issue 2Spring 2004 3-1-2004 Regulatory Arbitrage Strategies and Tactics in Telecommunications Rob Frieden Follow this and additional works at:http://scholarship.law.unc.edu/ncjolt Part of theLaw Commons Recommended Citation Rob Frieden,Regulatory Arbitrage Strategies and Tactics in Telecommunications, 5N.C. J.L. & Tech.227 (2004). Available at:http://scholarship.law.unc.edu/ncjolt/vol5/iss2/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Carolina Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in North Carolina Journal of Law & Technology by an authorized administrator of Carolina Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. NORTH CAROLINA JOURNAL OF LAW & TECHNOLOGY VOLUME 5, ISSUE 2: SPRING 2004 Regulatory Arbitrage Strategies and Tactics in Telecommunications I Rob Frieden Recently several states have launched investigations of certain MCI telephone call routings based on competitors' claims that the company eliminated or reduced payments it should have made.2 The MCI investigations may uncover instances of unlawful practices designed to shore up revenues, reduce payments to local exchange carriers for call delivery, avoid tax liability and shift local exchange access payment burdens to other carriers. Perhaps more significantly the investigations may trigger closer scrutiny of numerous strategies and tactics used by telecommunications carriers to reduce payments they make to other carriers. Also, this scrutiny may call attention to how carriers exploit inconsistent regulatory treatment of functionally the same services. A fuzzy line separates lawful efforts to achieve least cost routing of traffic on one hand, and deliberate efforts unlawfully to reduce or avoid financial obligations by deceiving other carriers as to where a call originated on the other hand.3 Regulatory asymmetry occurs when telecommunications service providers offer identical services, but incur different government oversight burdens. More extensive regulation, the duty to pay higher regulatory or legislative fees, and subsidy obligations may apply to carriers based on artificial classifications of services they offer such as geographical scope (intrastate versus interstate) and type (telecommunications as a stand alone service Rob Frieden is a Professor of Telecommunications at Pennsylvania State University. 2S ee, e.g., Stephen Labaton, MCIDisputesF raudC laim By AT&T, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 5, 2003, at Cl; Christopher Stem, WorldCom Says Its Probe Refutes AT&T Claim; BankruptP hone Firm Tells CourtN o Evidence Was Found That It DisguisedC alls to Avoid Fees, WASH. POST, Aug. 5, 2003, at El. 3 See Barnaby J. Feder, The Line Between Cost Management and Deceit, N.Y. TIMES, July 29, 2003, at Cl. 228 N.C. J.L. & TECH. [VOL. 5 versus one where telecommunications is a minor element of an information service). Additionally, inconsistent regulatory treatment may occur based on carrier classifications using historical market share and perceptions of its market power. Existing "legacy" regulatory classifications4 have established arbitrary dichotomies based on which regulatory agency has jurisdiction, what services qualify for promotion through favorable regulatory treatment, and how carriers and regulators decide to allocate costs. Regulatory arbitrage5 results when stakeholders, such as telecommunications service providers as MCI, exploit differences 4 The FCC has expressed a reluctance to apply legacy regulation when conditions change. "Given our attempts to reduce the regulatory burden on [incumbent local exchange carriers] ILECs, we are especially reluctant to impose similar legacy regulation on new competitive carriers." Access Charge Reform, 16 F.C.C.R. 9923, 9940 (2001). "I hope that, in future proceedings, the Commission will be quicker to recognize that the reflexive extension of legacy regulations to nascent technologies often harms the public interest." Provision of Improved Telecommunications Relay Services and Speech-to-Speech Services for Individuals with Hearing and Speech Disabilities, 18 F.C.C.R. 4761, 4774 (2003). 5 The FCC typically refers to regulatory arbitrage without providing a definition. "We recognize that the existing intercarrier compensation mechanism for the delivery of this traffic, in which the originating carrier pays the carrier that serves the ISP, has created opportunities for regulatory arbitrage and distorted the economic incentives related to competitive entry into the local exchange and exchange access markets." Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Intercarrier Compensation for ISP- Bound Traffic, Order on Remand and Report and Order, 16 F.C.C.R. 9151, 9152 (2001). One definition provided by the Commission characterizes regulatory arbitrage as "businesses making decisions based on regulatory classifications rather than on customers' preferences and innovative and sustainable business plans." Inquiry Concerning High-Speed Access to the Internet Over Cable and Other Facilities, Internet Over Cable Declaratory Ruling, 17 F.C.C.R. 4798, 4846 (2002). Another FCC definition is "profit-seeking behavior that can arise when a regulated firm is required to set different prices for products or services with a similar cost structure." Developing a Unified Intercarrier Compensation Regime, 16 F.C.C.R. 9610, 9616 n.18 (2001) [hereinafter Bill and Keep Carrier Compensation Proposal] (referencing PATRICK DEGRABA, BILL AND KEEP AT THE CENTRAL OFFICE AS THE EFFICIENT INTERCONNECTION REGIME 1 2 n.3 (F.C.C., O.P.P. Working Paper No. 33, 2000)); Patrick DeGraba, Central Office SPRING 20041 REGULATORY ARBITRAGE STRATEGIES 229 in legislative and regulatory classifications to accrue financial and competitive advantages achieved by avoiding regulatory burdens, or by foisting payment obligations onto other carriers. This article will examine tactics designed to exploit regulatory arbitrage with an eye toward identifying areas where inconsistent regulatory treatment distorts the competitive marketplace without offsetting public interest benefits. The article concludes that legislatures and regulators should eliminate opportunities to avoid regulatory burdens through routing and service classification tactics unless compelling reasons persist for maintaining regulatory asymmetry. The Federal Communications Commission and state public utility commissions have established numerous service definitions, territorial and cost allocation policies based on public policy or political considerations that have become unsustainable in light of technological developments. Many of these policies now have costs that exceed the public benefits particularly in light of the competitive distortions they create and the flawed justifications and assumptions underlying the policies. I. The Death of Distance Technological developments in telecommunications and information processing increasingly make it unsustainable for operators to charge distance sensitive (mileage based) rates.6 Much of the installed plant costs incurred by telecommunications carriers does not vary as a function of usage.7 Historically the FCC and state regulatory agencies have encouraged carriers to recover non-traffic sensitive costs on a metered basis8 and to Bill and Keep as a Unified Inter-CarrierC ompensation Regime, 19 YALE J. ON REG. 37 (2002). 6 See FRANCES CAIRNCROss, THE DEATH OF DISTANCE: HOW THE COMMUNICATIONS REVOLUTION WILL CHANGE OUR LIVES (1997). 7N on-traffic sensitive plant requires triggers costs that do not vary with the degree of use. For example, the costs of procuring and installing a telephone jack do not vary with the amount of calls made via that particular component. The FCC acknowledged the need to recover non-traffic sensitive costs on a flat-rate basis. "[N]on-traffic-sensitive costs-costs that do not vary with the amount of traffic carried over the facilities-should be recovered through flat- rate charges, and traffic-sensitive costs should be recovered through per-minute 230 N.C. J;L. & TECH. [VOL. 5 recover many types of both non-traffic sensitive and traffic sensitive costs by averazinz the different costs triggered by high and low volume-users. Cost averaging provides a simple "rough S- justice" solution to complex cost allocation problems,'0 but it blunts cost differences among carriers, routes and users. Inefficient and inequitable investment recovery would occur if carriers charged usage or mileage based charges to recoup such charges. This approach fosters competition and efficient pricing." Access Charge Reform Price Cap Performance Review for LECs, 18 F.C.C.R. 14,976, 14,977 (2003), available at 2003 WL 21544089. 9 Implicit subsidies in telecommunications "result, in large part from rate averaging between rural and suburban/urban areas and the recovery of certain non-traffic sensitive costs through traffic sensitive per minute rates, which over- recovers costs from higher volume users, often business customers." Review of the Section 251 Unbundling Obligations of Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers, CC Docket No. 01-338, 2003 WL 22175730, at *17078 n.509 (F.C.C. Aug. 21, 2003); see generally Access Charge Reform, Price Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers, Low-Volume Long Distance Users, Federal-State Joint Board On Universal Service, 15 F.C.C.R. 12,962, 12,971-72 (2002) (CALLS Order) (describing how high-volume users bear a greater share of the non-traffic sensitive costs than low-volume users), affd in part, rev'd in part, and remanded in part sub nom. Tex. Office of Pub. Util. Counsel v. Fed. Communications Comm'n, 265 F.3d 313 (5th Cir. 2001). 10 The 1996 Act requires cost averaging to achieve universal service objectives: Consumers in all regions of the Nation, including low-income consumers and those in rural, insular, and high cost areas, should have access to telecommunications and information services, including interexchange services and advanced telecommunications and information services, that are reasonably comparable to those services provided in urban areas and that are available at rates that are reasonably comparable to rates charged for similar services in urban areas. 47 U.S.C. § 254(b)(3) (2003). Additionally, the rates charged by providers of interexchange telecommunications services to subscribers in rural and high cost areas shall be no higher than the rates charged by each such provider to its subscribers in urban areas. Such rules shall also require that a provider of interstate interexchange telecommunications services shall provide such services to its subscribers in each State at rates no higher than the rates charged to its subscribers in any other State. Id. § 254(g). SPRING 2004] REGULATORY ARBITRAGE STRATEGIES sunk and embedded costs. High volume users would overcompensate the carrier while low volume users would underpay. Carriers should not bother to measure the distance between call originator and call recipient if the cost of such metering exceeds the cost differences in handling traffic of different distances. Telephone companies, particularly long distance carriers, typically average long and short haul traffic costs so that they can offer a single, flat rate for all calls. Data communications, including Internet-mediated services, have similar distance insensitive cost characteristics. Distance and traffic volume insensitivity means that telecommunications and Internet service providers can offer a single per minute or monthly rate for all calls within a wide geographical area, e.g., the entire United States for long distance telephone companies and the entire world for Internet Service Providers ("ISPs"). Such a "postalized" rate averages whatever cost differentials that still exist." Acknowledging the largely sunk investment in telecommunications plant, some carriers now offer a flat monthly rate for unlimited local and long distance calls. Such "All You Can Eat" pricing12 has become standard for Internet access in the United States, and ISPs have never priced access based on the distance separating users and the sources of content, or between senders and recipients of electronic mail. The death of distance largely erodes the rationale for using geography or political boundaries as the basis for differences in how carriers allocate costs and price services. Indeed many of the 11 For example, carriers typically still incur different, mileage-based carriers when they lease a dedicated line of varying distances. Local exchange carrier line transport charges are mileage-based when a single carrier leases a line instead of sharing it with other carriers. 12 ISPs initially offered unlimited Internet access to stimulate demand and considered unused network capacity as available for loading at little if any additional cost. Such promotional pricing does not burden heavy users with higher charges even though such rates could help ISPs recover fixed costs. Absent congestion ISPs could consider the incremental cost of handling more traffic as near zero. 232 N.C. J.L. & TECH. [VOL. 5 reasons for such differences never had a justification on the basis of cost as opposed to other political, social or public policy factors: [E]fficiency has not been the only goal of intercarrier compensation rules. For example, in order to encourage universal services, . .. [the Federal Communications] Commission and state regulators historically set access charges [paid to local exchange carriers] above cost. By doing so, they hoped to be able to keep local telephone rates low, and thus telephone penetration rates high.13 Federal and state telecommunications regulators previously saddled long distance callers, especially ones making intrastate calls, with higher rates than local telephone service consumers. Over-priced long distance call revenues made it possible for local exchange telephone companies ("LECs") to offer possibly below cost local services and to tap into subsidies for achieving universal service objectives including intentionally below cost service to rural residents, the poor and residents of tribal lands.14 13B ill and Keep Carrier Compensation Proposal, supra note 5, at 9623. 14" The Universal Service Fund now encompasses four programs that support telecommunications services nationwide. These include: Low-Income, High- Cost, Schools and Libraries, and Rural Health Care. Link-Up America (Link- Up) and the Lifeline Assistance Program (Lifeline) are part of the Fund's Low- Income Program." Federal Communications Commission, Get Connected: Afford-A-Phone, Background, availablea t http://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ getconnected/background.html (last modified Aug. 16, 2002) (on file with the North Carolina Journal of Law & Technology). Consumers qualifying for Link-Up America support are eligible to save up to 50% on initial installation fees, not to exceed $30 per household. In other words, up to $30 of the first $60 of their initial hook-up bill. Participants may also work with their telephone company to establish a deferred payment schedule for remaining costs of up to $200. Consumers living on American Indian or Alaskan Native tribal lands may also qualify for an additional $70 to defray initial connection charges. The Lifeline Assistance Program enables eligible low-income consumers to save from at least $6.75 to $9.50 on their basic monthly telephone service fee depending on the state where the consumer lives. Residents of tribal lands may be eligible SPRING 20041 REGULATORY ARBITRAGE STRATEGIES 233 Distance insensitivity in telecommunications also eliminates the rationale for having different charges for accessing the same local exchange facilities on the basis of whether the call crosses domestic or international borders, originates via a wireless or wireline carrier, or traverses the Internet. Yet LECs continue charging different rates largely because regulatory policies force them to do so, or political factors favor their decision to over- or under-price a particular service. Set out below is a continuum of LEC access costs from lowest to highest: * the exchange of traffic between an ISP and a LEC typically triggers no per minute access charge, because the ISP qualifies as an information service provider exempt from LEC access charge payment obligations making it possible for the ISP to receive and terminate calls via metered business telephone lines;15 • the exchange of traffic between LECs occurs on a reciprocal basis using zero cost, (bill and keep);' 6 for an additional $25 in savings on their basic monthly phone bill. Id. 15 "Since 1983, the Commission has consistently and consciously permitted enhanced service providers, a category that now includes Internet service providers (ISPs) to connect to their customers using local business lines." Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 14 F.C.C.R. 3689, 3690 n.1 (1999); see also MTS and WATS Market Structure, 97 F.C.C.2d 682, 715 (1983) (describing how the implementation of high carrier rates would experience severe rate impacts). "Enhanced service providers use interstate access but pay local business exchange service rates." Implementation of the Local Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 14 F.C.C.R. at 3690 n. 1. 16 Bill and Keep, sometimes referred to as Sender Keep All refers to an interconnection arrangement where a carrier agrees to accept traffic from another carrier in exchange for a reciprocal agreement. The carriers make no financial payments to each other. "The sharing of traffic over the interconnected networks forming the Internet on a statistical and un-metered 'settlements' (or 'bill & keep') basis was a hallmark of early federal agency involvement in the development of the Intemet. This system of traffic carriage free of charge became known as 'peering."' BARBARA ESBIN, INTERNET OVER CABLE: DEFINING THE FUTURE IN TERMS OF THE PAST 20 (F.C.C., O.P.P. Working Paper No. 30, 1998), available at 1998 WL 567433. 234 N.C. J.L. & TECH. [VOL. 5 negotiated, or regulatory-agency prescribed rates typically at a rate several decimal places below one cent;17 the exchange of traffic between long distance, i.e., interexchange carriers ("IXCs") and LECs occurs on a uniformly tarriffed basis with rates that have declined substantially, but still significantly exceed the reciprocal rates paid by LECs; 18 New Competitive Local Exchange Carriers ("CLECs") typically charge IXCs higher access fees than Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers ("ILECs");19 Section 251 (b)(5) of the Telecommunications Act of 1996 requires all local 17 exchange carriers "the duty to establish reciprocal compensation arrangements for the transport and termination of telecommunications." 47 U.S.C. § 251 (b)(5) (2001). For examples of the quite small rates ILECs charge for local facilities, see National Regulatory Research Institute, A Survey of UnbundledN etwork Element Prices in the United States (July 2003), at http://nrri.org/documents/ Matrix0703all.pdf (comparing loop and port rates as well as tandem switching and transport rates for state access lines) (on file with the North Carolina Journal of Law & Technology); Jeffrey H. Rohlfs & J. Gregory Sidak, Exporting Telecommunications Regulation: The UnitedS tates-JapanN egotiations on InterconnectionP ricing,4 3 HARV. INT'L L.J. 317, 340 (2002) (listing the local interconnection rates for selected states in 1999). 18 In 2000, the FCC adopted an industry proposed access charge regime that increased user fees but reduced interexchange carrier access charge payments to ILECs to a target range of 0.55 cents for the Regional Bell Operating Companies and GTE, 0.65 cents for other LECs subject to price cap regulation, and 0.95 cents LECs operating in areas with low subscriber densities. For example, the Commission approved lower switching and transport access services to a target range of 0.62. "We also adopt target rates of 0.55 cents for the BOC price cap LECs and GTE, 0.95 cents for very low-density price cap LECs, and 0.65 cents for other price cap LECs." See Matter of Access Charge Reform, 15 F.C.C.R. 12,962, 13,029 162 (2000), rev'd in part by Texas Office of Public Utility Counsel v. Fed. Communications Comm'n, 265 F.3d 313 (5th Cir. 2001) (No. 00-60434), cert. denied by Nat'l Ass'n of State Util. Consumer Advocates v. Fed. Communications Comm'n, 535 U.S. 986 (2002), on remand to Cost Review Proceeding for Residential and Single-Line Business Subscriber Line Charge (SLC) Caps, 17 F.C.C.R. 10,868 (F.C.C. Jun. 5, 2002), availablea t 2002 WL 1213038. 19" Our review of the record reveals that CLEC access rates vary quite dramatically and, on the average, are well above the rates that ILECs charge for similar service." Access Charge Reform, Reform of Access Charges Imposed by Competitive Local Exchange Carriers, 2001 WL 431685, 22 (F.C.C. Apr. 7, 2001); see also Access Charge Reform Price Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers, 15 F.C.C.R. 12,962, 13,028 (2000) (describing how SPRING 20041 REGULATORY ARBITRAGE STRATEGIES 235 the exchange of traffic between a wireless carrier and a wireline LEC carrier depends on whether the call appears to be a local exchange of traffic (even if originated at a long distance), or one involving a conventional long distance 20 call making the range variable; the exchange of international long distance traffic on routes lacking significant competition occurs on a per minute accounting rate,21 ranging from a few cents to more than the commission's current price cap plan allows price cap LECs flexibility to determine tandem-switch rates), partially reverseds ub nom. Tex. Office of Pub. Util. Counsel v. Fed. Communications Comm'n, 265 F.3d 313 (5th Cir. 2001), cert. denied, 535 U.S. 986 (2002), on remand, Cost Review Proceeding for Residential and Single-Line Business Subscriber Line Charge (SLC) Caps, 17 F.C.C.R. 10,868 (2002). 20 For example, in 2001 Sprint PCS charged AT&T 2.8 cents per minute to deliver AT&T long distance calls to Sprint PCS subscribers. Petitions of Sprint PCS and AT&T Corp. For Declaratory Ruling Regarding CMRS Access Charges, WT Docket No. 01-316, Declaratory Ruling, 17 F.C.C.R. 13,192 (2001). This rate matched what major wireline LECs charged interexchange carriers, but ran counter to the traditional access pricing mechanism for wireless carriers where subscribers of the wireless carrier compensate it for the cost of both sending and receiving calls: CMRS carriers have never operated under the same calling party's network pays (CPNP) compensation regime as wireline LECs. Under a CPNP regime, LECs are compensated for terminating calls by the carrier of the customer that originates the call, not by the customer receiving the call. In contrast, since the advent of commercial wireless service, and continuing today, CMRS carriers have charged their end users both to make and to receive calls. Until 1998, when Sprint PCS first approached AT&T and other IXCs about payment for terminating access service, all CMRS carriers recovered the cost of terminating long distance calls from their end users, and not from interexchange carriers.... The fact that the industry practice for 15 years has been for CMRS carriers to recover costs from their end users, together with the highly competitive nature of the interexchange market, makes it unlikely that an IXC that does not pay access charges to CMRS carriers somehow "overcharges" its customers. Id.a t 13,198. 21 For background on the international long distance telephone toll revenue division process see ROB FRIEDEN, MANAGING INTERNET-DRIVEN CHANGE IN INTERNATIONAL TELECOMMUNICATIONS ch. 9.1 (2001); Robert M. Frieden,
Description: