Monetary Reformers, Amateur Idealists and Keynesian Crusaders Australian Economists’ International Advocacy, 1925-1950 by Sean Turnell BEc (Hons) A thesis submitted in fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Department of Economics Division of Economic and Financial Studies Macquarie University 1999 TABLE OF CONTENTS Abstract Acknowledgements Chapter One: Introduction 1.0 Introductory Comments 9 1.1 Aims and Significance of this Research 11 1.2 Limitations of this Research 13 1.3 Outline of the Study 14 Section I: Monetary Reformers Introduction 20 Chapter Two: Cheap Money and Ottawa 2.0 Australian Economists and Monetary Reform 22 2.1 The Wallace Bruce Report and Keynes 31 2.2 Ottawa 38 2.3 Matters of Theory 44 2.4 Chosen Instrument: British Monetary Policy 51 Chapter Three: The World Economic Conference 3.0 Preparation 54 3.1 The Conference 60 3.2 Aftermath 64 Section II: Amateur Idealists Introduction 68 Chapter Four: F.L. McDougall 4.0 ‘Sheltered Markets’ 72 4.1 Disillusionment 74 4.2 The ‘Nutrition Approach’ 77 4.3 Economic Appeasement 82 4.4 Propagating Economic Appeasement 89 4.5 Influence, Achievements and Underconsumption 91 2 Section III: Keynesian Crusaders Introduction 101 Chapter Five: The Beginnings of the ‘Employment Approach’ 5.0 Article VII 105 5.1 The ICER Report 117 5.2 The ‘Clearing Union’ 119 Chapter Six: Coombs and Consolidation 6.0 Coombs 130 6.1 Old Themes at Hot Springs 137 6.2 Keynes, London and a Diversion in Philadelphia 145 Chapter Seven: Bretton Woods 7.0 The Joint Statement 157 7.1 The Conference 165 Chapter Eight: An International Employment Agreement 8.0 Approach to the United States 175 8.1 The United Nations 179 8.2 The Beginning and the End of the ITO 181 Chapter Nine: The ‘Employment Approach’ Reconsidered 9.0 Theoretical Coherence 190 9.1 The Approach as Political Economy 196 Section IV: Keynesian ‘Revolutionaries’ Chapter Ten: The Keynesian ‘Revolution’ in Australia 10.0 The Existing Literature 207 10.1 The Contribution of this Study 216 Section V: Concluding Comments Chapter Eleven: Conclusion 11.0 Conclusion 227 11.1 Extensions of this Research 231 Bibliography 232 3 Abstract Between 1925 and 1950, Australian economists embarked on a series of campaigns to influence international policy-making. The three distinct episodes of these campaigns were unified by the conviction that ‘expansionary’ economic policies by all countries could solve the world’s economic problems. As well as being driven by self-interest (given Australia’s dependence on commodity exports), the campaigns were motivated by the desire to promote economic and social reform on the world stage. They also demonstrated the theoretical skills of Australian economists during a period in which the conceptual instruments of economic analysis came under increasing pressure. The purpose of this study is to document these campaigns, to analyse their theoretical and policy implications, and to relate them to current issues. Beginning with the efforts of Australian economists to persuade creditor nations to enact ‘cheap money’ policies in the early 1930s, the study then explores the advocacy of F.L. McDougall to reconstruct agricultural trade on the basis of nutrition. Finally, it examines the efforts of Australian economists to promote an international agreement binding the major economic powers to the pursuit of full employment. The main theses advanced in the dissertation are as follows: Firstly, it is argued that these campaigns are important, neglected indicators of the theoretical positions of Australian economists in the period. Hitherto, the evolution of Australian economic thought has been interpreted almost entirely on the basis of domestic policy advocacy, which gave rise to the view that Australian economists before 1939 were predominantly orthodox in theoretical outlook and policy prescriptions. However, when their international policy advocacy is included, a quite different picture emerges. Their efforts to achieve an expansion in global demand were aimed at alleviating Australia’s position as a small open economy with perennial external sector problems, but until such international policies were in place, they were forced by existing circumstances to confine their domestic policy advice to orthodox, deflationary measures. Secondly, the campaigns make much more explicable the arrival and dissemination of the Keynesian revolution in Australian economic thought. A predilection for expansionary and proto-Keynesian policies, present within the profession for some time, provided fertile ground for the Keynesian revolution when it finally arrived. Thirdly, by supplying evidence of expansionary international policies, the study provides a corrective to the view that Australia’s economic interaction with the rest of the world has largely been one of excessive defensiveness. Originality is claimed for the study in several areas. It provides the first comprehensive study of all three campaigns and their unifying themes. It demonstrates the importance to an adequate account of the period of the large amount of unpublished material available in Australian archives. It advances ideas and policy initiatives that have hitherto been ignored, or only partially examined, in the existing literature. And it provides a new perspective on Australian economic thought and policy in the inter-war years. 4 Acknowledgements In undertaking a project as large as this, I have acquired a great many debts to a great many people. Most of these debts are far too big and intangible ever to be repaid. One of the nice things about doing a Ph.D thesis, however, is that you can make a small down-payment by thanking some of these people in print. First of all, I would like to thank my supervisor, Professor Rod O’Donnell. A great teacher and scholar, Rod had to endure quite a number of drafts of this work, and his advice and suggestions on these is greatly appreciated. Two other members of the Economics Department at Macquarie University, Michael Dobbie and Bill Junor, also read this thesis in its entirety. Both put aside work that was far more urgent and undoubtedly more in their personal interests in order to do so. Their generosity is more appreciated than I can say. I would like to single out the ‘lunchtime mafia’ of Associate Lecturers in the Economics Department for special thanks. Wylie Bradford, Michael Dobbie, Craig Macmillan, Joe Macri and Alison Vicary have helped me in more ways than I suspect they can imagine. First class intellects all, their generosity of spirit, their myriad of kindnesses, the general joy I have experienced in their company, kept the dark times at bay and gave to me the things that only true friends can give. Three great friends (and former housemates), Tinzar Lwyn, Leanne Ussher and Alison Vicary, had to live with this project for such a long time that it must have seemed that Frank McDougall himself was a member of the household. My time with them is something that I will treasure always. Friends generally have been of great assistance to me in completing this work. Ross and Maureen Brown, Tony Bryant, Hester Barrington-Ward, David Maher, Justin Myatt, Gary Pflugrath, Lynden and Marelle Sharpe, Kathryn Matthews, Hermyleen Walker - and many others whom I have undoubtedly, and unforgivably, forgotten to mention, have helped me in myriad ways. I would also like to thank former colleagues at the Reserve Bank of Australia for getting me started. I would like to especially acknowledge Glenn Worley for a friendship that has lasted all my life. Above all I would like to thank my parents, Peter and Diana Turnell, for making possible the extraordinary idea that their son could work towards a Ph.D. They sacrificed much to ensure that I had the opportunity to receive an education that made this possible. More than this though, they created a loving and liberal environment in which anything that was good and decent was seen to be possible. My sister and brother-in-law, Lisa and Michael Brandt, occupy a similarly central place. To the thrill of all, my new nephew, Timothy, arrived just in time for the party. 5 Notwithstanding the help I have received from all of the above, this thesis remains solely the responsibility of its author, who therefore deserves and accepts the blame for any of its deficiencies. 6 This work is dedicated to Peter and Diana Turnell and to the memory of William and Jessie Turnell and Reginald and Dulcie Fraser 7 The belief that we have come from somewhere is closely linked with the belief that we are going somewhere. A society which has lost belief in its capacity to progress in the future will quickly cease to concern itself with its progress in the past. E.H. Carr, 1961 8 INTRODUCTION 1.0 Introductory Comments On 30 May 1945, Australia’s Minister for Post-War Reconstruction, J.J. Dedman, tabled Full Employment in Australia before the Commonwealth Parliament. The product of countless drafts and compromises, this ‘White Paper’ was an extraordinary testimony to the extent to which ‘Keynesian economics’ had taken root in Australia. Declaring that it was the responsibility of governments to stimulate spending on ‘goods and services to the extent necessary to sustain full employment’, the White Paper explicitly recognised Keynes’s central point that aggregate demand was the primary determinant of employment. Breaking aggregate demand into the components familiar to any modern student of introductory macroeconomics - private consumption, private capital expenditure, government spending and net exports - the White Paper identified private capital expenditure as one of the chief sources of instability of demand and employment. This was consistent with Keynes’s prognostications and with similar documents issued overseas, as was its solution to the problem of deficient demand by both compensatory public expenditure and monetary measures to encourage private spending. In contrast to its overseas counterparts, however, private capital expenditure was not identified by the White Paper as the chief source of fluctuations in demand and employment. The chief source of unstable demand in Australia, rather, was instability in export income. Unstable export income was, indeed, doubly cursed - for not only was it a source of demand instability itself, but it was also an important constraint on government policies designed to alleviate other sources of deficient demand. Of course, the White Paper’s identification of the external sector as the principal constraint on the domestic economy was hardly new. A preoccupation with external balance and a ‘brooding pessimism’ about its prospects has been a defining feature of Australian economic thought for many years (Corden 1968, p.15). It was also the motivation for the relatively numerous contributions of Australian economists to the literature devoted to trade and protection, perhaps the area in which they have made their greatest additions to the sum of economic knowledge. The preoccupation with external balance had previously produced a number of devices designed to manage it, but almost all of these (captured under the guiding philosophy of ‘New Protection’) involved the restriction of imports in some way. In the White Paper, ‘protection’ was not disavowed, but it took a back seat to a complementary policy which its authors regarded as much more in keeping with the spirit of its times. This policy took the form of a proposal that the Commonwealth Government seek agreement with other nations to enter into a binding commitment with each other ‘to do all in their power to maintain employment within their own territories, and thereby expand demand for internationally-traded goods’. Called variously by Dr. H.C. 9 (Nugget) Coombs, one of the principal authors of the White Paper, the ‘positive approach’, ‘Australia’s international Keynesian crusade’ or, most popularly of all, the ‘employment approach’, it was a policy which informed Australia’s positions to all the conferences concerned with the reconstruction of the world economy during, and immediately after, the Second World War (Coombs 1981, p.35). Devised by Coombs, Giblin, Melville and other influential economists from the ‘golden age of Australian economics’, the ‘employment approach’ was motivated by the concerns for external balance (Groenewegen and McFarlane 1990, p.118). It was also self-consciously an attempt to apply what its authors believed to be Keynesian economics on a global scale. Self-interested and theoretically innovative, the employment approach was the product of a generation impressed by Marshall’s dictum that it was with ‘cool heads but warm hearts’ that economists should go out into the world.1 This ‘radical and distinctly Australian’ approach was not, however, the first time Australian economists had embarked upon a programme which combined the traditional anxieties for external balance with theoretical innovation and a Marshallian sense of mission. Two earlier campaigns, shorn of the model fully developed by Keynes in the General Theory, but inclusive nevertheless of many of the ideas which led to it, had been initiated by Australians in the previous two decades. The first of these, the product of Giblin, Melville and the ‘older’ group of professional economists in the vanguard of the employment approach, was concerned with attempts to convince the world’s creditor nations of the efficacy of expansionary monetary policies as the solution to the global Depression. These efforts, which were the basis of Australia’s approach to the Imperial Economic Conference at Ottawa in 1932, and to the World Monetary and Economic Conference in London in 1933, ultimately foundered upon the breakdown of the latter. With it went the last hope of a multilateral solution to the problems of the global economy before the Second World War. The second campaign began after the failure of the World Monetary and Economic Conference. Advanced by F.L. McDougall, an influential amateur in a long tradition of Australian economics, the ‘nutrition approach’ was hawked around creditor nations throughout the latter half of the 1930s. It called for a reorganisation of world agriculture along lines of comparative advantage through the elimination of agricultural protection, with simultaneous public spending initiatives designed to improve living standards. These ideas were an intellectual extension of earlier efforts by McDougall, in company with the then Prime Minister of Australia, S.M. Bruce, to build a prosperous and well-populated Australia within a reforming British Empire. Broadened into a campaign of ‘economic appeasement’, McDougall’s propagation of his nutrition ideas continued into the war years where it interconnected with the employment approach - completing a neat circularity of ideas which seemed to foreign observers as something quite distinctively Australian. This perception of foreign observers was a real one. It is a proposition of this thesis that the approaches outlined above represented a consistent line of advocacy, one which should be considered as a counter to the protectionist and syndicalist themes traditionally associated with Australia’s interaction with the world. 1 Marshall cited in Smyth (1994), p.26. 10
Description: