ebook img

Effects of Deregulation on Safety [electronic resource] : Implications Drawn from the Aviation, Rail, and United Kingdom Nuclear Power Industries PDF

248 Pages·2003·28.1 MB·English
by  BierVicki
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Effects of Deregulation on Safety [electronic resource] : Implications Drawn from the Aviation, Rail, and United Kingdom Nuclear Power Industries

EFFECTS OF DEREGULATION ON SAFETY: Implications Drawn/rom the Aviation, Rail, and United Kingdom Nuclear Power Industries EFFECTS OF DEREGULATION ON SAFETY: lmplications Drawnfrom the Aviation, Raii, and United Kingdom Nuclear Power lndustries Vicki Bier University of Wisconsin-Madison US.A. James Joosten Connect-USA.com LLC US.A. David Glyer Jennifer Tracey and Michael Welsh Christensen Associates US.A. SPRINGER SCIENCE+BUSINESS MEDIA, LLC Effects of deregulation on safety: implieations from the aviation, raii, and United Kingdom nuclear power industries / Vieki Bier ... (et al.). p.em. Includes bibliographieal referenees and index. ISBN 978-1-4613-4991-4 ISBN 978-1-4615-0259-3 (eBook) DOI 410.1007/978-1-4615-0259-3 1. Deregulation--Great Britain--Case studies. 2. Industrial safety-- Great Britain--Case studies. 1. Bier, Vieki HD3616.G72 E37 2002 363.11 "2"0941--de21 2002040685 Copyright © 2003 by Springer Science+Business Media New York Originally published by Kluwer Academic Publishers in 2003 Softcover reprint ofthe hardcover Ist edition 2003 AII rights reserved. No part ofthis work may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, microfilming, recording, or otherwise, without the written permission from the Publisher, with the exception of any material supplied specificalIy for the purpose of being entered and executed on a computer system, for exclusive use by the purchaser of the work. Permission for books published in Europe: [email protected] Permissions for books published in the United States of America: [email protected] Printed on acid-free paper. The Publisher offers discounts on this book for course use and bulk purchases. For furtlrer information, send email to<[email protected]> . TABLE OF CONTENTS Page Table of Contents v Acknowledgments and Disclaimer vii 1. Introduction 1 2. Aviation Deregulation Literature Review 11 3. A viation Industry Interviews 43 4. Rail Deregulation Literature Review 61 5. Rail Industry Interviews 85 6. United Kingdom Electricity Supply Industry Deregulation Literature Review 111 7. United Kingdom Electricity Supply Industry Interviews and Safety Audits 131 8. Relevance of Case Studies to the U.S. Nuclear Power Industry 173 9. Summary and Conclusions 215 References 227 Index 241 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The authors wish to acknowledge the staff of the U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Commission Human Factors Branch (especially Paul Lewis, the project monitor) for their support of this research, and for providing timely assistance in obtaining needed information. We would also like to acknowledge the contributions of all the interviewees who generously shared their time and expertise to help us understand the effects of deregulation and restructuring on their industries. They include: John Baker, Norman Callaghan, Anne Campbell, Michael Harrison, Peter Haslam, John McNamara, and Jeremy Western of British Energy; Alan Bleeze, Michael Jeal, Craig Reiersen, and J. L. Summers of the United Kingdom Health and Safety Executive; Pearl Marshall (a United Kingdom trade press correspondent); and numerous anonymous representatives of trade unions, safety regulators, and the U.S. aviation and rail industries. The case study of the United Kingdom electricity supply industry draws heavily from the masters thesis of James Joosten (Department of Engineering Physics, University of Wisconsin-Madison), titled The Impacts of Restructuring the Electricity Market on Nuclear Safety: Lessons Learned from the United Kingdom. Finally, the authors acknowledge Lesley Klein for her help and patience in typing and formatting this manuscript. DISCLAIMER This report was prepared as an account of work sponsored by an agency of the United States Government. Neither the United States Government nor any agency thereof, nor any of their employees, makes any warranty, expressed or implied, or assumes any legal liability or responsibility for any third party's use or the results of such use, of any information, apparatus, product, or process disclosed in this report, or represents that its use by such third party would not infringe privately owned rights. The views expressed in this report are not necessarily those of the U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Commission. In particular, the recommendations presented are those of the authors, not of the U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Commission. Chapter 1 INTRODUCTION 1.1 BACKGROUND Safety is widely recognized to be a paramount concern in the nuclear power industry. Currently, extensive changes are taking place in the U.S. nuclear industry due to economic deregulation of electricity. Therefore, it is important to understand the potential effects ofe lectricity deregulation on safety. The purpose of this book is to shed light upon this issue. We begin this chapter with a brief overview of the concept of economic deregulation, as implemented both in the U.S. electricity industry and in other industries. We then discuss the approach taken in this book to understanding the effects of deregulation on nuclear power safety. In particular, our approach rests on a detailed review of how economic deregulation has affected safety in three other industries with important similarities to the U.S. nuclear power industry-namely, the U.S. air and rail industries, and the nuclear power industry in the United Kingdom (U.K.). 1.2 HISTORY OF DEREGULATION Many services that we think of as being traditional "utility" services-such as electricity, natural gas, and telephone-have been subject to economic regulation. This regulation is primarily on the prices and profits of private firms, but may also encompass service characteristics, and typically places restrictions on the entry of firms to the industry. An alternative form of market control is to supply the service using government-controlled or government-operated firms. In the U.S., private firms have provided most utility services, but in other countries (including much of Western Europe), such utility services have commonly been provided by government-owned organizations. Other industries-such as trucking, aviation, and rail-have also been subject to economic regulation, even in "free market" economies such as those of the U.S. and Western Europe. Economists have spent considerable effort analyzing the incentives created by economic regulation, and the economic rationale for regulation. See for example Kahn (1970) for a definitive treatment of regulation at the beginning of the deregulation movement, and Joskow and Noll (1981) for an overview of regulation in theory and practice. One widespread conclusion from this body of 2 Introduction work has been that economic regulation is associated with substantial costs, in the form of both inefficient production processes and an inefficient mix of services. Further, deregulation diminishes the incentives to innovate, which in the end can impose even greater costs. Many economists have therefore argued that market provision of services can be significantly more efficient than economic regulation and/or government ownership. By the 1960s and 1970s, there was considerable pressure for reform and deregulation of economically regulated industries, especially in the U.S., based largely on a growing recognition of the costs of regulation. This led eventually to deregulation of the rail, trucking, aviation, natural gas, petroleum, and telecommunications industries. The move to deregulation cut across political J lines. As noted by Weiss and Klass (1986, pg. 1), "Three successive presidents-Nixon, Ford, and Carter-took active roles in the regulatory reform movement, each sending numerous proposed bills on the topic to Congress. Reagan also supported it.. . [although] most of the big changes had already been made when he reached office." The process of deregulation continued under the administrations of Presidents Bush and Clinton. The experience in deregulated industries has shown that deregulation creates both winners and losers. However, the consensus among economists is that, overall, the various experiments with deregulation have been beneficial. A number of studies of deregulation (see for example Weiss and Klass, 1986; Crandall and Ellig, 1997) have estimated the savings to be substantial; Crandall and Ellig estimate that the savings in the U.S. have amounted to tens of billions of dollars per year for each of several deregulated industries. Moreover, post deregulation assessments of the economic benefits have generally been at least comparable to the ranges of benefits expected beforehand, and in several cases significantly greater (Crandall and Ellig, 1997). Deregulation of electricity service in the u.S. has come somewhat later than deregulation of the other industries discussed above; several factors helped to pave the way for the eventual deregulation of U.S. electricity markets (see for example a summary by U.S. Department of Energy, 2002a). First, although slower than technological changes in the airline and telecommunications industries, changes in generation technology (especially the development ofless expensive and more efficient gas turbines) reversed the trend towards increasing economies of scale at the level of individual generators.2 This allowed for increased competition in wholesale electric power markets. Second, deregulation and privatization of electricity markets elsewhere in the world (including the u'K., Norway, Australia, and New Zealand) demonstrated the feasibility of restructuring and deregulation. This was important, since economic regulation of electricity markets in the U.S. is more complex than regulation of most other industries. In particular, electricity regulation in the U.S. is split between state public utility commissions and the federal government. The states have been Effects of Deregulation on Safety 3 reticent to cede their regulatory powers, so the federal government has been unable to act independently and unilaterally to restructure electricity markets. Several institutional and legal changes were important building blocks towards electricity deregulation in the U.S. First, passage of the Public Utilities Regulatory Policies Act (PURP A) in 1978 allowed non-utility generators to construct "qualified" cogeneration facilities that could sell power to the electric utilities. PURP A provided a mechanism for independent power producers to enter the wholesale electricity market, facilitating the development of the sorts of non-regulated generating companies that would eventually become the cornerstone of a competitive market (although the criteria for becoming a qualified facility were quite restrictive). In addition, many states implemented PURP A in ways that increased electricity prices for customers (in some cases substantially), increasing the incentives for deregulation. In fact, the states that had artificially high prices due to such problems (for example, California, New York, and most of New England) were among the first to move toward deregulation. Subsequently, the Energy Policy Act of 1992 gave the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) expanded authority over wholesale power markets, contributing to deregulation of the wholesale markets.3 The FERC has utilized its authority to gradually "un-bundle" the more competitive market functions (especially electricity generation) from the transmission and distribution functions, which retain more of the characteristics of a natural monopoly.4 In particular, the FERC issued a sequence of important regulations that further opened the wholesale power markets. In 1996, FERC Orders 888 and 889 improved the access ofi ndependent power producers to the transmission network, and helped put them on a more even footing with the electric utilities. Several years later, Order 2000 provided for the establishment of "regional transmission organizations" (RTO's) to operate the regional transmission networks independently ofthe electric utilities, even when the utilities actually own the networks. (Prior to Order 2000, many utilities had been operating their transmission networks in ways that favored their own customers and generating facilities at the expense of other generating companies, circumventing the intent of previous FERC actions.) Most recently, in July 2002, FERC issued a notice of proposed rulemaking on standard market design to restructure the wholesale electricity market in the U.S., simultaneously ensuring fairer access to the transmission grid and reducing the ability of generating companies to exercise monopoly power (Burkhart, 2002). In combination, the various FERC orders provided the impetus for deregulation in the U.S. wholesale electricity market, and aided in deregulation of state-regulated retail markets. Note that the FERC cannot actually require retail competition, since the retail markets are the purview of state public utility commissions. However, in many states, utility commissions or legislatures have introduced retail competition, in which individual consumers or firms can choose 4 Introduction their own electricity suppliers rather than purchasing all electricity from local (regulated monopoly) utility companies. Typically, these state actions have also resulted in divestiture of some or all of the generation facilities owned by the existing utilities. Thus, by now, deregulation of both wholesale and retail electricity markets in the U.S. has been evolving for the past decade, with wholesale deregulation generally preceding retail deregulation. National legislation and FERC orders implemented many aspects of wholesale competition and deregulation in the mid 1990's; many states (including California, New York, most of New England, Pennsylvania, Ohio, Illinois, and Texas) have since implemented at least partial retail competition, beginning with California in 1998 (U.S. Department of Energy, 2002b). Most recently, problems with the restructured electricity markets in California (see for example Brennan, 2001) have halted progress towards deregulation of retail electricity markets in many states that had not already adopted or fully implemented relevant legislation. However, many economists believe that the fundamental arguments for deregulation are still sound. Therefore, FERC restructuring of wholesale electricity markets is continuing. Retail markets will likely also see additional deregulation after state legislators and regulators have assimilated the lessons from the California experience, and have confidence that they can design deregulated electricity markets to avoid problems similar to those that occurred in California. 1.3 RATIONALE FOR THIS STUDY It is reasonable to believe that the effects of economic deregulation of electricity generation will be seen across a broad spectrum of safety-related areas in the U.S. nuclear power industry. The objective of this book is to provide a comprehensive overview of those consequences of electricity deregulation in the U.S. that have the potential to affect the risk of nuclear power plants. In particular, we were interested in the effects of deregulation on: 1) Equipment failure rates, and the quantity and quality of maintenance (e.g., the level of expenditures on preventive maintenance); 2) Equipment aging; 3) Financial pressures; 4) Factors affecting human error rates and experience levels (e.g., downsizing, use of overtime and contractors, loss of institutional memory, employee morale, and training); 5) Labor relations; 6) Mergers, acquisitions, and other major management changes; and

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.