ebook img

A nonextensive approach to the dynamics of financial observables PDF

0.43 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview A nonextensive approach to the dynamics of financial observables

A nonextensive approach to the dynamics of financial observables S´ılvio M. Duarte Queir´os,∗ Luis G. Moyano,† and Jeferson de Souza‡ Centro Brasileiro de Pesquisas F´ısicas, 150, 22290-180, Rio de Janeiro - RJ, Brazil Constantino Tsallis§ Santa Fe Institute, 1399 Hyde Park Road, Santa Fe - NM, USA and Centro Brasileiro de Pesquisas F´ısicas, 150, 22290-180, Rio de Janeiro - RJ, Brazil 6 (Dated: February 2, 2008) 0 We present results about financial market observables, specifically returns and traded volumes. 0 They are obtained within the current nonextensive statistical mechanical framework based on the 2 an entropy Sq = k1−1iWP−=1qpqi (q∈ℜ) (S1 ≡ SBG = −kiPW=1pi lnpi). More precisely, we present stochas- J tic dynamical mechanisms which mimic probability density functions empirically observed. These mechanismsprovidepossible interpretations fortheemergence of theentropicindices q in thetime 1 3 evolution of the corresponding observables. In addition to this, through multi-fractal analysis of return time series, we verify that the dual relation qstat+qsens = 2 is numerically satisfied, qstat ] and qsens being associated to the probability density function and to the sensitivity to initial con- n ditions respectively. This type of simple relation, whose understanding remains ellusive, has been a empirically verified in various other systems. - a t a I. INTRODUCTION where p is the probability of the microscopic configura- d i tion i [1]. The Boltzmann principle should be derivable . s In recent years statistical mechanics has enlarged its frommicroscopicdynamics,sinceitreferstomicroscopic c i originalassignment: the applicationof statistics to large states, but the implementation of such calculation has ys systems whose states are governed by some Hamilto- not been yet achieved. So, Boltzmann-Gibbs (BG) sta- h nianfunctional[1]. Itscapabilityforrelatingmicroscopic tisticalmechanicsis stillbasedonhypothesissuchasthe p statesofindividualconstituentsofasystemtoitsmacro- molecularchaos[4]andergodicity[5]. Inspiteofthelack [ scopic properties are nowadays used ubiquitously [2]. of an actual fundamental derivation, BG statistics has Certainly,themostimportantoftheseconnectionsstillis been undoubtedly successfulin the treatmentof systems 1 v the determination of thermodynamic properties through in which short spatio/temporal interactions dominate. 2 the correspondence between the entropy concept, origi- For such cases, ergodicity and (quasi-) independence are 2 nallyintroducedbyRudolfJulius EmmanuelClausiusin favoured and Khinchin’s approach to SBG is valid [5]. 2 1865 [3], and the number of allowed microscopic states, Therefore, it is entirely feasible that other physical en- 1 introduced by Ludwig Boltzmann around 1877 when he tropies, in addition to the BG one, can be defined in 0 was studying the approach to equilibrium of an ideal ordertoproperlytreatanomaloussystems,forwhichthe 6 gas [4]. This connection can be expressed as simplifyinghypothesisofergodicityand/orindependence 0 are not fulfilled. Examples are: metastable states in / s S =k lnW, (1) long-rangeinteracting Hamiltonian dynamics, metaequi- c libriumstatesinsmallsystems(i.e.,systemswhosenum- i where k is a positive constant, and W is the number s ber of particles is much smaller than Avogrado’s num- y of microstates compatible with the macroscopic state of ber),glassysystems,sometypesofdissipativedynamics, h an isolated system. This equation, known as Boltzmann p principle,isoneofthecornerstonesofstandardstatistical and other systems that in some way violate ergodicity. v: mechanics. Thisincludessystemswithnon-Markovianmemory(i.e., long-rangememory),likeitseemstobethecaseoffinan- i When the system is not isolated, but instead in con- X cial ones. Generically speaking, systems that may have tact to some large reservoir, it is possible to extend Eq. r (1),undersomeassumptions,andobtaintheBoltzmann- a multi-fractal, scale-free or hierarchicalstructure in the a occupancy of their phase space. Gibbs entropy Inspired by this kind of systems it was proposed in W 1988 the entropy [6] S =−k p lnp , (2) BG i i Xi=1 1− W pq i S =k iP=1 (q ∈ℜ), (3) q q−1 ∗e-mailaddress: [email protected] whichgeneralisesS (lim S =S ),asthebasisof †e-mailaddress: [email protected] BG q→1 q BG ‡e-mailaddress: [email protected] apossiblegeneralisationofBGstatisticalmechanics[7,9]. §e-mailaddress: [email protected] The value of the entropic index q for a specific system 2 is to be determined a priori from microscopic dynamics. JustlikeS ,S isnonnegative,concave,experimentally BG q [p(x)]q robust (or Lesche-stable [10]) (∀q >0), and leads to a (x−µ¯ )2 dx≡ (x−µ¯ )2 =σ¯2, (8) finiteentropy production per unit time [2,11]. Moreover, Z q [p(x)]qdx D q Eq q it has been recently shown [12] that it is also extensive, R correspondingtothegeneralised meanandvarianceofx, i.e., respectively [9]. N From the variational problem using (5) under the Sq(A1+A2+...+AN)≃ Sq(Ai), (4) above constraints, we obtain Xi=1 1 for special kinds of correlated systems, more precisely p(x)=A 1+(q−1)B (x−µ¯ )2 1−q , (q <3), q q q when the phase-space is occupied in a scale-invariant h i (9) form. By being extensive, for an appropriate value of where, q, S complies with Clausius’ concept on macroscopic q entropy, and with thermodynamics. sevSeirnaclerietssupltrsoipnosbaolt,henfutrnodpaym(e3n)tahlaasnbdeeanpptlhieedsopuhrycseicosf, A = ΓΓ[[2512−−−−23qqqq]]q1−πqBq ⇐ q <1 , (10) as well as in other scientific areas such as biology, chem- q  Γ[q−11] q−1B ⇐ q >1 istry, economics, geophysics and medicine [13]. Herein, Γ[23q−−q2]q π q we both review and present some new results concern-  and ing applications to the dynamics of financial market ob- servables, namely the price fluctuations and traded vol- B = (3−q) σ¯2 −1. (11) q q umes. Specifically, we will introduce stochastic dynam- (cid:2) (cid:3) ical mechanisms which are able to reproduce some fea- Standard and generalised variances, σ¯2 and σ¯2 respec- q tures of quantities such as the probability density func- tively, are related by tions (PDFs) and the Kramer-Moyal moments. More- over, we will present some results concerning the return 5−3q σ¯2 =σ¯2 . (12) multi-fractal structure, and its relation to sensitivity to q 3−q initial conditions. Our dynamical proposals will be faced to empirical Defining the q-exponential function as analysis of 1 minute returns and traded volumes of the 30 companies that were used to compose the Dow Jones ex ≡[1+(1−q) x]1−1q (ex ≡ex), (13) q 1 Industrial Average (DJ30) between the 1st July and the 31st December 2004. In order to eliminate specious be- (exq =0 if 1+(1−q)x≤0) we can rewrite PDF (9) as haviourswe have removedthe well-knownintra-daypat- tern following a standard procedure [8]. After that, the p(x)=A e−Bq(x−µ¯q)2, (14) q q returnvalueswere subtractedfromits averagevalue and expressedinstandarddeviationunits,whereasthetraded hereafter referred to as q-Gaussian. volumes are expressed in mean traded volume units. For q = 3+m, the q-Gaussian form recovers the Stu- 1+m dent’s t-distribution with m degrees of freedom (m = 1,2,3,...) with finite moment up to order mth. So, II. VARIATIONAL PRINCIPLE USING THE for q > 1, PDF (14) presents an asymptotic power- ENTROPY Sq law behaviour. On the other hand, if q = n−4 with n−2 n = 3,4,5,..., p(x) recovers the r-distribution with n Before dealing with specific financial problems, let us degrees of freedom. Consistently, for q < 1, p(x) has analyse the probability density function which emerges a compact support which is defined by the condition when the variational principle is applied to Sq [9]. |x−µ¯ |≤ 3−q σ¯2. Let us consider its continuous version, i.e., q q1−q q 1− [p(x)]q dx S =k . (5) q R1−q III. APPLICATION TO MACROSCOPIC OBSERVABLES The natural constraints in the maximisation of (5) are A. Model for price changes p(x) dx=1, (6) Z TheGaussiandistribution,recoveredinthelimitq →1 corresponding to normalisation, and of expression (14), can be derived from various stand- [p(x)]q points. Besides the variational principle, it has been de- x dx≡hxi =µ¯ , (7) Z [p(x)]qdx q q rived, through dynamical arguments, by L. Bachelier in R 3 his1900workonpricechangesinParisstockmarket[14], Itisthisfactwhichallowedtheestablishmentofanalogies and also by A. Einstein in his 1905 article on Brownian (currently used in financial mimicry) between financial motion [15]. In particular, starting from a Langevin dy- markets dynamics and fluid turbulence [20]. namics, we are able to write the corresponding Fokker- Itisnoteworthythateq. (16)isstatisticallyequivalent Planck equation and, from it, to obtain as solution the to [18, 21] Gaussian distribution. Analogously, it is also possible, from certain classes of stochastic differential equations dr =−krdt+Aq(t) dWt+(q−1)Bq(r,t) dWt′, (20) and their associated Fokker-Planck equations, to obtain i.e., a stochastic differential equation with independent the distribution given by Eq. (14). additive and multiplicative noises. If eq. (15) allows an Inthissection,wewilldiscussadynamicalmechanism immediate heuristic relation between q and the response forreturns,r,whichisbasedonaLangevin-likeequation of the system to its own dynamics, eq. (20) permits thatleadstoaPDF(q-Gaussian)withasymptoticpower- a straighforward dynamical relation between q and the law behaviour [16, 17]. This equation is expressed as magnitude of multiplicative noise in sucha waythat, for q = 1, the Langevin equation is recovered as well as the dr =−krdt+ θ [p(r,t)](1−q)dW (q ≥1), (15) t Gaussian distribution. q InFig.(1)wepresentthetypicalPDFforthe1minute (inItoˆ convention)whereW is aregularWiener process t returnsofacompanyconstituentoftheDowJonesIndus- and p(r,t) is the intantaneous return PDF. In a return trialAverage30(upperpanel)presentingq =1.31±0.02, contextthedeterministictermofeq. (15)intendstorep- a time series generated by eq. (15) (middle panel), and resent internal mechanisms which tend to keep the mar- the U-shaped 2nd Kramers-Moyal moment for our data ket in some averagereturn or, in a analogousinterpreta- (lowerpanel). Asitcanbeseentheaccordanceusingthe tion, can be related to the eternal competition between simplestapproachisalreadyquite nice. Upgradesofthis speculative price and the actual worth of a company. In model can be obtained by taking into account the risk- our case, we use the simplest approach and write it as aversion effects, which induce asymmetry on the PDF, a restoring force, with a constant k, similar to the vis- and correlations on the volatility in a way which differs cousforceinthe regularLangevinequation. Inregardto from others previously proposed. The formulation pre- thestochasticterm,itaimstoreproducethemicroscopic sented herein has also the advantage of being aplicable response of the system to the return: θ is the volatility to systems which are not in a stationary state since the constant(intimately associatedtothe varianceofp(r,t)) time-dependent solutions of the Fokker-Planck equation and q, the nonextensive index, reflects the magnitude of are of the q-Gaussian type as well. that response. Since the largestunstabilities in the mar- ketareintroducedbythemostunexpectedreturnvalues, it is plausible that the stochastic term in Eq. (15) can B. Model for traded volumes have such inverse dependence on the PDF p(r,t). Fur- thermore, Eq. (15) presents a dynamical multiplicative Changes in the price of a certain equity are naturally noise structure given by, dependent on transactions ofthat equity and thus on its r(t)=Z t e−k(t−t′)qθ[p(r,t)](1−q) dWt′, (16) ttoratidcedpovwoelur-mlaew, vb.ehParveivouiorusofstturaddieesdpvroolvuemdethPeDaFsy[m22p]-, −∞ later extended for all values of v [23]. In this case it was where we have assumed r(−∞)=0. shownthatthetradedvolumePDFisverywelldescribed The associated Fokker-Planck equation to Eq. (15) is by the following ansatz distribution given by 1 v ρ v ∂p(r,t) = ∂ [krp(r,t)]+ 1 ∂2 θ [p(r,t)](2−q) , P (v)= Z (cid:18)ϕ(cid:19) expq(cid:18)−ϕ(cid:19), (21) ∂t ∂r 2∂r2 n o (17) where v represents the traded volume expressed in its and the long-term probability density function is[16, 18, mean value unit hVi, i.e., v = V/hVi, ρ and ϕ are pa- 19], rameters, and Z = ∞ v ρexp −v dv. 0 ϕ q ϕ 1 kr2 1−1q The probability dRensi(cid:16)ty(cid:17)function(cid:16)(21)(cid:17)was recently ob- p(r)= 1−(1−q) . (18) Z (cid:20) (2−q) Zq−1θ(cid:21) tained from a mesoscopic dynamical scenario [24] based inthefollowingmultiplicativenoisestochasticdifferential One of the most interesting features of eq. (15) is its equation aptitude to reproduce the celebrated U-shape of the 2nd (i.e., n=2) Kramers-Moyalmoment ω γ dv =−γ(v− )dt+ 2 vdW , (22) α r α t M (r,t,τ)= (r′−r)n P (r′,t+τ|r,t) dr′ ≈τθ [p(r,t)](1−q) . n Z where Wt is a regular Wiener process following a nor- (19) mal distribution, and v ≥ 0. The right-hand side terms 4 FIG. 2: Symbols represent the average correlation function forthe30timeseriesanalysedandthelinerepresentsadouble exponentialfit with characteristic times of T =13 and T = 1 2 332 yielding a ratio about 25 between the two time scales Eq. (24) (R2 = 0.991, χ2 = 9×10−6, and time is expressed in minutes). inverted Gamma stationary distribution: 1 v −α−2 ω f(v)= exp − . (23) ωΓ[α+1] ω v (cid:16) (cid:17) h i Consider now, that instead of being a constant, ω is a time dependent quantity which evolves on a time scale T larger than the time scale of order γ−1 required by eq. (22) to reach stationarity [25, 26]. This time depen- dence is, in the present model, associated to changes in thevolumeofactivity(numberoftradersthatperformed transactions) and empirically justified through the anal- ysis of the self-correlationfunction for returns. In Fig. 2 wehaveverifiedthatthecorrelationfunctionisverywell described by C[v(t),v(t+τ)]=C e−τ/T1 +C e−τ/T2 (24) 1 2 with T = 332 ≫ T = 13. In other words, there is FIG. 1: Upper panel: Probability density function vs. r. 2 1 first a fast decay of C[v(t),v(t+τ)], related to local Symbols correspond to an average over the 30 equities used equilibrium, and then a much slower decay for larger τ. tobuiltDJ30andthelinerepresentsthePDFobtainedfrom Thisconstitutesanecessaryconditionfortheapplication a time series generated by eq. (16) which is presented on middle panel. Lower panel: 2nd Kramers-Moyal moment of a superstatistical model [25]. M ≈ τθ [p(r)](1−q) = τ k (5−3q)σ2+(q−1)r2 from If we assume that ω follows a Gamma PDF, i.e., 2 2−q which k parameter is obtained(cid:2)and where the stationa(cid:3)ry hy- pothesis is assumed (t0 = −∞ ≪ −k−1 ≪ 0). Parameter P(ω)= 1 ω δ−1exp −ω , (25) values: τ = 1min, k = 2.40±0.04, σ = 0.930±0.08 and λΓ[δ](cid:16)λ(cid:17) h λi q=1.31±0.02. then, the long-term distribution of v will be given by p(v)= f(v) P (ω) dω. This results in R 1 v −α−2 θ p(v)= exp − , (26) Z (cid:16)θ(cid:17) q(cid:20) v(cid:21) of eq. (22) represent inherent mechanisms of the sys- tem in order to keep v close to some “normal” value, where λ = θ(q−1), δ = q−11 −α−1. Bearing in mind ω/α, and to mimic microscopic effects on the evolution that, for q >1, of v, like a multiplicative noise commonly used in inter- 1 minigttFenotkkperro-Pcelsasnecsk. eTqhuiastdioynna[m18i]c,s,leaanddttohethceorfroelslopwonindg- xae−q xb =(cid:20)q−b 1(cid:21)q−1 xa−q−11 eq−b/(qx−1)2, (27) 5 Analogously, it was recently conjectured [28] that, for systemswhichcanbestudiedwithinnonextensivestatis- tical mechanics, the energy probability density function (associated to stationarity or (meta) equilibrium), the sensitivity to the initial conditions, and the relaxation would be described by three entropic indices q , q , stat sens and q , referred to as the q-triplet. The first physi- rel cal corroboration of such scenario has been made from the analysis of two sets of daily averages of the mag- netic field strength observed by Voyager 1 in the solar wind [29]. Others systems are currently on study (e.g., [30]). Ofcourse,if the system is non Hamiltonian, it has noenergydistribution, henceq cannotdefined inthis stat manner. We may howeverestimate it through a station- ary state generalised Gaussian (which would generalise the Maxwellian distribution of velocities for a BG sys- tem in thermal equilibrium). In contrast, the other two indices, q and q , remain defined in the usual way. sens rel Let us focus now on the multi-fractal structure of re- turn time series. It has been first conjectured, and later proved,foravarietyofnonextensiveone-dimensionalsys- tems, that the following relation holds [31]: 1 1 1 = − , (28) 1−q h h sens min max where h and h are respectively the minimal and FIG. 3: Upper panel: Excerpt of the time series generated min max maximal h-values of the associated multifractal spec- by our dynamical mechanism (simulation) to replicate 1 min trum f(h). In fig. 4 we depict the multifractal spec- traded volume of Citigroup stocks at NYSE (data). Lower trumof 1minute tradedvolumes,obtainedby the appli- panel: 1 min traded volume of Citigroup stocks probability densityfunctionvs. tradedvolume. Symbolsarefordata,and cation of the MF-DFA5 method [32]; h and f(h) have solidlineforthereplica. Parametervalues: θ=0.212±0.003, been obtained from averages of the empirical data of 30 ρ = 1.35 ± 0.02, and q = 1.15 ± 0.02 (χ2 = 3.6 × 10−4, companies. Through this analysis, we have determined R2 =0.994). h = 0.28± 0.04 and h = 0.83± 0.04. The use min max of Eq. (28) yields q = 0.58±0.10. Considering that sens the q value obtained for the return probability density wecanredefineourparametersandobtaintheq-Gamma function was q =1.31±0.02, we verify that the dual stat PDF (21). relation InFig.3wepresentacomparationbetweenthetraded volume of Citigroup (2004 world’s number one company q +q =2 (29) stat sens [27]) stocks, as well as a replica of that time series ob- tainedusingthisdynamicalproposal. Asitcanbeeasily isapproximatelysatisfiedwithintheerrorintervals. Tak- verified, the agreement is remarkable. ingintoaccountthe well-knownfastdecayofreturnself- correlations, we see that the price changes for a typical DJ30 stock may be essentially described by the q-triplet IV. THE NONEXTENSIVE q-TRIPLET AND {q ,q ,q }={0.58±0.10,1.31±0.02,1}. sen stat rel FINANCIAL OBSERVABLES Systems characterised by Boltzmann-Gibbs statistical V. FINAL REMARKS mechanicspresentthefollowingcharacteristics: (i)Their PDF for energies is proportional to an exponential func- In this article we have presented a nonextensive sta- tioninthepresenceofathermostat;(ii)Theyhavestrong tistical mechanics approach to the dynamics of finan- sensitivity to the initial conditions, i.e., this quantity in- cial markets observables, specifically the return and the creases exponentially with time (currently referred to as traded volume. With this approach we have been able strong chaos), being characterised by a positive maxi- to present mesoscopic dynamical interpretations for the mum Lyapunov exponent; (iii) They typically present, emergenceofthe entropicindexq frequentlyobtainedby for basic macroscopic quantities, an exponential decay a numerical adjustment for data PDF of eqs. (18) and with some relaxation time. In other words, these three (21). For the case of returns, q is related to the reaction behaviours exhibit exponential functions (i.e., q = 1). degree of the agents on the marketto fluctuations of the 6 the stationary state, the sensitivity to initial conditions, and the relaxation for nonextensive systems. The com- plete understanding of these connections remains ellu- sive. Forinstance,concerningrelaxationandtheq-triplet conjecture, a new question arise for price changes. It is well-known that the self-correlation for returns is of ex- ponential kind, in contrast with the long-lasting correla- tions for the volatility (or returns magnitude) [33]. The latter is also considereda stylisedfact and it is compati- blewithaq-exponentialform. Inthisway,iftheefficient markethypothesisisconsideredthekeyelementinfinan- cialmarkets,thenitmakessensetoassumeq =1. But, rel if arbitrage on markets is considered as the fundamental feature instead, then the essentialrelaxationto be taken FIG.4: Multi-fractalspectrumf(h)vs. hfor1minutereturn averaged over the 30 equities with h = 0.28±0.04 and intoaccountmightbetheonerelatedtothevolatility,for min hmax =0.83±0.04. which qrel > 1. Progress is clearly still needed, at both the fundamentalandappliedlevels,inorderto achievea deep understanding of this complex system. observable,whileforthe caseoftradedvolumeitisasso- ciated to fluctuations on the (local) average traded vol- ume. Along with these dynamical scenarios, and based We thank Olsen Data Services for the data provided on the multi-fractal nature of returns, we have verified and used herein. Financial support from PRONEX and thatthisquantityappearstoapproximativelysatisfythe CNPq (Brazilian agencies), FCT/MCES (Portuguese dual relation, q +q = 2, previously conjectured agency),andSIInternationalandAFRL(USAagencies), stat sens within the emergenceofthe q-tripletwhichcharacterises is also acknowledged. [1] K. Huang, Statistical Mechanics, (John Wiley & Sons, (2006), in press [cond-mat/0411073]; C. Tsallis, Milan NewYork, 1963). Journal of Mathematics 73, 145 (2005); C. Tsallis, M. [2] M. Gell-Mann and C. Tsallis (eds.), Nonextensive En- Gell-MannandY.Sato,Proc.Natl.Acad.Sci.USA102, tropy-InterdisciplinaryApplications,(OxfordUniversity 15377(2005);C.Tsallis, M.Gell-MannandY.Sato,Eu- Press, NewYork, 2004). rophysics News 36, 186 (2005). [3] E. Fermi, Thermodynamics, (Doubleday, New York, [13] Nonextensive Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 1936). edited by S. Abe and Y. Okamoto, Lecture Notes in [4] L. Boltzmann, Lectures on Gas Theory, (Dover, New Physics 560 (Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg, 2001); Non- York,1995). Extensive Thermodynamics and Physical Applications, [5] A.I. Khinchin, Mathematical Foundations of Informa- edited by G. Kaniadakis, M. Lissia, and A. Rapisarda tion Theory (Dover,New York,1957) and Mathematical [Physica A 305 (2002)]; Anomalous Distributions, Non- Foundations of Satistical Mechanics (Dover, New York, linear Dynamics and Nonextensivity, edited by H. L. 1960). Swinney and C. Tsallis [Physica D 193 (2004)]; Nonex- [6] C. Tsallis, J. Stat. Phys. 52, 479 (1988). Bibliography tensive Entropy - Interdisciplinary Applications, edited URL:http://tsallis.cat.cbpf.br/biblio.htm. by M. Gell-Mann and C. Tsallis (Oxford University [7] E.M.F.CuradoandC.Tsallis,J.Phys.A24,L69(1991); Press, New York, 2004); Complexity, Metastability and Corrigenda: 24, 3187 (1991) and 25, 1019 (1992). Nonextensivity,editedbyC.Beck,G.Benedek,A.Rapis- [8] A.AdmatiandP.Pfleiderer,Rev.Fin.Stud.1,3(1988); arda and C. Tsallis (World Scientific, Singapore, 2005); Y. Liu, P. Gopikrishnan, P. Cizeau, M. Meyer, C.-K. Nonextensive statistical mechanics: newtrends, new per- Peng and H.E. Stanley,Phys. Rev.E 60, 1390 (1999). pectives, edited by J.P. Boon and C. Tsallis, Europhys. [9] C. Tsallis , R.S. Mendes and A.R. Plastino, Physica A News 36 (6) (2005). 261, 534 (1998). [14] L. Bachelier, Th´eorie de la sp´eculation, Ann. Sci. E´cole [10] B. Lesche, J. Stat.Phys. 27, 419 (1982) Norm. Sup.III-17, 21 (1900). [11] V. Latora and M. Baranger, Phys. Rev. Lett. 273, 97 [15] A. Einstein, Ann.der Phys. 17, 549 (1905). (1999). [16] L. Borland, Phys. Rev.E 57, 6634 (1998). [12] C.Tsallis,inComplexity,MetastabilityandNonextensiv- [17] S.M. Duarte Queir´os, Quantit. Finance 5, 475 (2005); ity,editedbyC.Beck,G.Benedek,A.RapisardaandC. S.M. DuarteQueir´os, working paper CBPF-NF-027/05. Tsallis (World Scientific, Singapore, 2005), page 13; Y. [18] H.Risken,The Fokker-Planck Equation: Methods of So- Sato and C. Tsallis, Proceedings of the Summer School lution and Applications, 2nd edition (Springer-Verlag, and Conference on Complexity (Patras and Olympia, Berlin, 1989). July 2004), edited by T. Bountis, G. Casati and I. Pro- [19] A.R. Plastino, A. Plastino, Physica A 222, 347 (1995); caccia, International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos C.Tsallis,D.J.Bukman,Phys.Rev.E54,R2197(1996). 7 [20] S.Ghashghaie, W.Breymann,J.Peinke,P.Talknerand [26] S.M. DuarteQueir´os, Europhys.Lett. 71, 339 (2005). Y.Dodge, Nature381, (1996) 767. [27] http://www.forbes.com [21] C. Anteneodo and C. Tsallis, J. Math. Phys. 44, 5194 [28] C. Tsallis, Physica A 340, 1 (2004). (2003). [29] L.F.BurlagaandA.F.-Vin˜as,PhysicaA356,375(2005). [22] P.Gopikrishnan,V.Plerou,X.GabaixandH.E.Stanley, [30] B.M.BoghosianandE.P.Borges,privatecommunication Phys.Rev.E 62, R4493 (2000). (2005). [23] R. Osorio, L. Borland and C. Tsallis, in Nonextensive [31] M.L.LyraandC.Tsallis,Phys.Rev.Lett.80,53(1997). Entropy - Interdisciplinary Applications, M. Gell-Mann [32] J.W.Kantelhardt,S.A.Zschiegner,E.Koscielny-Bunde, andC.Tsallis(eds.)(OxfordUniversityPress,NewYork, S.Havlin,A.BundeandH.E.Stanley,PhysicaA316,87 2004). (2002). [24] J. de Souza, L.G. Moyano and S.M. Duarte [33] H.E. Stanley, L.A.N. Amaral, P. Gopikrishnan and V. Queir´os, Eur. Phys. J. B (in press, 2006), preprint Plerou, Physica A 283, 31 (2000) arXiv:physics/0510112. [25] C. Beck and E.G.D. Cohen, Physica A 322, 267 (2003).

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.